iconOpen Access

ARTICLE

crossmark

Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading Method of Multi-Virtual Power Plants Based on Non-Cooperative Game

Jingjing Bai*, Hongyi Zhou, Zheng Xu, Yu Zhong

Yancheng Power Supply Company of State Grid Jiangsu Electric Power Co., Ltd., Yancheng, 224008, China

* Corresponding Author: Jingjing Bai. Email: email

Energy Engineering 2023, 120(5), 1163-1183. https://doi.org/10.32604/ee.2023.025553

Abstract

The current electricity market fails to consider the energy consumption characteristics of transaction subjects such as virtual power plants. Besides, the game relationship between transaction subjects needs to be further explored. This paper proposes a Peer-to-Peer energy trading method for multi-virtual power plants based on a non-cooperative game. Firstly, a coordinated control model of public buildings is incorporated into the scheduling framework of the virtual power plant, considering the energy consumption characteristics of users. Secondly, the utility functions of multiple virtual power plants are analyzed, and a non-cooperative game model is established to explore the game relationship between electricity sellers in the Peer-to-Peer transaction process. Finally, the influence of user energy consumption characteristics on the virtual power plant operation and the Peer-to-Peer transaction process is analyzed by case studies. Furthermore, the effect of different parameters on the Nash equilibrium point is explored, and the influence factors of Peer-to-Peer transactions between virtual power plants are summarized. According to the obtained results, compared with the central air conditioning set as constant temperature control strategy, the flexible control strategy proposed in this paper improves the market power of each VPP and the overall revenue of the VPPs. In addition, the upper limit of the service quotation of the market operator have a great impact on the transaction mode of VPPs. When the service quotation decreases gradually, the P2P transaction between VPPs is more likely to occur.

Keywords


1  Introduction

In recent years, the advantages of distributed energy development have gradually emerged, and it has become inevitable for the energy supply mode to transform from centralized to distributed [13]. However, China’s existing power generation/power supply mode is mainly a centralized operation with high sensitivity, a large amount of communication information, and low robustness. It cannot give full play to the advantages of distributed energy in security and economy, leading to the low marketization degree of distributed energy and the need for relevant national policy support. Under the background of deepening reform of the electric power system, various countries have accelerated the development of distributed market trading [46]. China released in November 2017 Notice on Developing Distributed Power Generation Market Trading Pilot, which puts forward to further open the user side market, play the positive guidance of market, and stimulate the vitality of market entities. In this context, a local power-sharing and trading method–Peer-to-Peer (P2P) energy trading method emerged. It can effectively lower the threshold and trading cost of the user-side market trading and stimulate the enthusiasm of market entities to participate in distributed trading. Now, it has been widely used in power trading between virtual power plants (VPPs). However, distributed energy trading still faces problems, such as random user behavior, random bidding strategy of each entity, and complex market relations. Therefore, it is urgent to optimize the market trading strategy of each entity and further clarify the game relationship between different market entities.

At present, the forms of power sharing and distributed trading between VPPs can be divided into the following two categories [7]: (1) Energy sharing and trading system based on cooperative game mode; (2) Energy sharing and trading system based on a non-cooperative game. For the former, its main form is that each VPP participates in the overall market trading in the form of an alliance and preferentially consumes the internal surplus electric energy in the form of energy sharing. Reference [8] proposed a cooperative game model based on one-to-many and many-to-many trading, and uses the nucleolus method to realize the redistribution of the cooperative surplus. References [9,10] improved the nucleolus method by clustering and calculating the excess degree, making it suitable for a large number of VPP groups. Reference [11] proposed a building group day-ahead optimal scheduling strategy based on energy sharing, and uses the Shapley value method to redistribute the overall revenue after scheduling. For the latter, different from a cooperative game, the electric energy trading mode based on a non-cooperative game focuses on the equilibrium under the conflict of interest between each entity, which can be divided into the platform-leading trading mode and participant-leading trading mode. References [12,13] built a platform-leading market trading model, where leading market operators and followers form a Stackelberg game relationship. Through electricity price guide and electric power sharing, it promotes the nearby consumption of clean energy, and reduces the transmission loss in the energy trading process. Reference [14] studied the participant-leading non-cooperative game model, establishes the non-cooperative competitive relationship between multiple sellers, and obtains the optimal bidding strategy of each seller based on the Nash equilibrium solution. Reference [15] combined the two forms with both the master-slave game relationship between agents and VPP, and the evolutionary game relationship between multiple VPP. Reference [16] presented a non-cooperative game model for optimal dispatching of virtual power plants considering distribution network security. Reference [17] provided the distributed transaction model considering the energy consumption characteristics of end users, and used the non-cooperative game model to analyze the game relationship between sellers and sellers and buyers in the process of P2P transaction. Reference [18] analyzed the seller’s price competition and buyer’s choice competition in the process of P2P trading through non-cooperative game theory and evolutionary game theory.

Based on the cooperative or non-cooperative game method, the above Reference studies the distributed trading between VPPs. But there are still the following deficiencies on the whole: First, in addition to electricity price and electricity these two variables directly related to trading results, the energy consumption characteristics and controllable potential of end users are also important factors. Although existing researches involve the load demand response of VPPs, they fail to systematically evaluate the VPP scheduling potential from the perspective of users’ energy consumption characteristics. Secondly, current research on P2P trading mode based on the non-cooperative game is mostly confined to analysis of the VPP trading strategy and energy management strategy at the game equilibrium point. Few conduct an in-depth analysis of the conditions and influencing factors of P2P from the perspective of game equilibrium.

From the above considerations, this paper proposes a VPP Peer-to-Peer energy trading method based on the non-cooperative game. Firstly, combined with operating principles of public building central air-conditioning system, a VPP day-ahead scheduling framework including public buildings is built. Next, the utility function for electric power sellers during the P2P trading process from the perspective of trading profit, service cost, power generation cost is constructed. And the non-cooperative game model between seller VPP and market operator (market operator, MO) is established. Then, the game model Nash equilibrium solution is summarized according to the definition of pure strategy Nash equilibrium, and the rationality of Nash equilibrium solution is also proved. Finally, through simulation example, the impact of different air conditioning operation strategies on P2P trading results is compared and the conditions and influencing factors of P2P trading between VPPs are also analyzed.

2  VPP Operation Framework and Basic Model

This paper mainly studies public building aggregations, energy storage, photovoltaic, and fixed load VPPs. Meanwhile, the type of VPPs aggregated public buildings varies, including but not limited to large shopping malls, office buildings and hotels. The main controllable equipment within the building is the central air conditioning system, which can optimize the operation mode of different units through a flexible control strategy, to save power consumption and improve the VPPs’ market schedulable potential. The basic VPP structure of aggregated public buildings is shown in Fig. 1.

images

Figure 1: Schematic diagram of VPP basic structure

2.1 Central Air-Conditioning System Model in Public Buildings

Compared with distributed air conditioners on the resident side or in small factories, the central air conditioners in large public buildings are more centralized with larger controllable capacity. The existing public building central air conditioning operation strategy is mostly the constant temperature operation at a preset temperature. However, as long as the building room temperature is within a certain temperature range, there will not be much change in the user comfort [19,20]. Therefore, the energy consumption characteristics of the end-user equipment could be adjusted properly. For example, through flexible control of chillers and water pumps, the central air conditioning operation strategy could be optimized to reduce the VPP load demand and improve the VPP market trading potential. In this paper, the comfort requirements of users are determined using the predicted mean vote (PMV) index [21,22], denoted as σPMV, which represents the thermal sensation registered by a majority of people within the same environment. Also its basic operation principle is shown in Appendix A.

To ensure human comfort within an acceptable range, the present work applies the following constraint to the regulation and control processes of CACSs based on σPMV:

0.5σPMV0.5(1)

The relationship between σPMV and the indoor temperature Tin can be expressed as follows:

σPMV={0.3895×(Tin26),Tin260.4065×(Tin+26),Tin<26(2)

Therefore, the reasonable temperature range of human comfort can be determined according to Eqs. (1) and (2).

According to the principle of energy conservation, the actual heat obtained by a public building in a certain period of time is equal to the difference between the incoming heat and the heat taken away by the central air conditioner. As shown in Fig. 2, that is, in any period of time, the sum of the instantaneous heat gain Qcl of public buildings, the outside air Qnw and the thermal energy storage Qx of the building structure is equal to cooling capacity Qe of the air-conditioning system. And the public buildings instantaneous heat gain Qcl are composed by the transient heat transfer of external walls and roofs hourly cooling load Qwq, the transient heat transfer of external windows hourly cooling load Qwc, the solar radiation heat through glass windows hourly cooling load Qfs, the indoor electrical equipment hourly cooling load for heat dissipation Qel, the heat dissipation of indoor lighting equipment hourly cooling load Ql, and the heat dissipation of the indoor human body hourly cooling load Qp.

images

Figure 2: Schematic diagram of cooling and heating load balance

Public building air conditioning system regulation should meet the room temperature requirement of building users. This paper uses the modeling method based on cold and heat load calculations to describe the public building heat storage model. For public buildings, the central air conditioners provide a cooling load inside the buildings during work. Meanwhile, the heat release from the heat source inside and outside the building as well as heat storage of the building’s interior wall constantly raises the room temperature. Therefore, the heat balance relationship is as follows [23]:

CaVkρadTin=Qcldt+QnwdtQxQedt(3)

Here, Qcl, Qnw, Qx and Qe respectively represent the public building instantaneous heat, outside air load, thermal energy storage capacity of building structure, and hourly cooling capacity of chillers; Tin is the building room temperature; Ca is the air specific heat at constant pressure, Vk is the building refrigerating volume, and ρa is the air density. Combined with the above thermodynamic equations, the public building heat storage model of the central air conditioning refrigeration effect is derived:

γdTindt+βTin(αQe)=0(4)

Here, γ, β and α are the parameters respectively describing weather conditions and building heat storage characteristics. The specific calculation method is shown in [24]. The following room temperature hourly-varying equation is derived from Eq. (4):

Tin(t)=eβγΔtTin(t1)+(1eβγΔt)[α(t)βQe(t)β](5)

As can be seen from Eqs. (3)(5), to keep the room temperature within a certain range, the central air conditioning system needs to coordinate each unit’s operation to produce a stable cooling capacity. The central air conditioning system of a public building is mainly composed of three circulation systems: chilled water loop, condenser water loop, and refrigerant loop.

The cooling process of the central air conditioning system is to use electricity to move the indoor heat to the outdoor. For an air conditioning system with N1 chillers, N2 chilled water pumps, N3 cooling coil fans, N4 condenser water pumps, and N5 cooling towers, the energy consumption model can be expressed as [25]:

Phvac=i=1N1Pchiller,i+j=1N2PCHWpump,j+k=1N3Pcoil,k+m=1N4PCWpump,m+n=1N5Ptower,n(6)

Here, Pchiller,i, PCHWpump,j, Pcoil,k, PCWpump,m and Ptower,n respectively indicate the energy consumption of chillers, chilled water pumps, condenser water pumps, fan coils, and cooling towers. The energy consumption of each part is calculated as follows:

(1) Chiller

Chiller is the core of the central air conditioning system, and its energy consumption mainly depends on its energy efficiency ratio:

Pchiller,i=QeCOP(7)

Here, Qe is the cooling load of the chilled water loop, and COP is the air conditioning coefficient of performance. COP is calculated from the chiller evaporating temperature, condensing temperature, and load rate:

COP=r(Tc+273.15Te+273.151)r+a1Tc+273.15Te+273.15a2(8)

Here, r is the chiller load rate, which can be expressed as a ratio of the cooling load Qe to the rated load Qnom. Te is the evaporating temperature and Tc is the condensing temperature, which can be calculated from the following formula:

Te=TchwrQeFchw(mchw)(9)

Tc=Tcws+QcFcw(mcw)(10)

Here, Tchwr and Tcws represent the water temperature of return chilled water and temperature of supply condenser water, respectively. Qc represents the load of the condenser water loop. Fchw(mchw) and Fcw(mcw) are the empirical formulas for a chilled water flow mchw and condenser water flow mcw.

(2) Frequency conversion water pump

At present, most water pumps in building air conditioning systems operate at rated power, which leaves relatively large space for optimization. This paper assumes that all water pumps are installed with the frequency control system to control flow and reduce energy consumption. The power calculation formula of the frequency conversion water pump is as follows:

Qroom.k=cc,1,kmsa,kcc,3,k1+cc,2,k(msa,kmchw,k)cc,3,k(Tma,kTchws)(11)

Here, Qroom.k is the cooling load of the corresponding area. msa,k and mchw,k are the fan air flow and chilled water flow in the coil, respectively; Tchws indicates the supply chilled water temperature, and Tma,k is the mixed indoor and outdoor air temperature, which can be expressed as Tma,k=0.25Tout+0.75Tkin. Meanwhile, the sum of chilled water flow in the coil equals the total chilled water flow in the system:

j=1N2mchw,j=k=1N3mchw,k(12)

(3) Cooling tower

The cooling tower is the heat exhaust device of the central air conditioning system, which absorbs the heat in the room and discharges it to the outside through a condenser water loop. The heat dissipation process can be expressed as:

i=1N1Qc,i=n=1N5cc,1,tmta,ncc,3,t1+cc,2,t(mta,nmcw,n)cc,3,t(TcwrTwb)(13)

Here, mta,n and mcw,n are the airflow and condenser water flow respectively in the cooling tower; Tcwr and Twb are the temperatures of return chilled water and cooling tower wet bulb temperature, respectively. In addition, the total condenser water flow in the air conditioning system remains unchanged:

m=1N4mcw,m=n=1N5mcw,n(14)

(4) Fan coil

The energy consumption of the fan coil and cooling tower both comes from fans. The energy consumption model is similar to that of the frequency conversion pump, which can be expressed as:

Pcoil/tower=kfXa(1eAfXsa)ηvar(Xa)(15)

Xsa/ta=msa/tamsa/ta.nom(16)

Here, msa/ta.nom is the rated value of the fan coil and cooling tower airflow.

(5) Operation constraints of the central air-conditioning system

Operation constraints of the central air-conditioning system mainly include operation constraints of each device and interaction constraints between different devices, where the interaction between the chiller and chilled/condenser water loop can be expressed as:

i=1N1Qe,i=(m=1N2mchw.m)cw(TchwrTchws)(17)

i=1N1Qc,i=(n=1N3mcw.m)cw(TcwrTcws)(18)

Here, based on the energy balance principle, condenser water eliminates the heat on the condenser water side, including heat generated by the compressor, and heat transmitted from evaporator to condenser through on the chilled water circulation side. Therefore, in the condenser water loop the cooling load Qc,i=Qe,i+Pchiller,i.

To ensure the optimal performance of the air conditioning system, variables should in the acceptable range.

Tchws.minTchwsTchws.max(19)

Tcws.minTcwsTcws.max(20)

mchw,j.minmchw,jmchw,j.max(21)

mcw,j.minmcw,jmcw,j.max(22)

msa,k.minmsa,kmsa,k.max(23)

mta,n.minmta,nmta,n.max(24)

Formulas (19) and (20) set the upper and lower limits of chilled water and condenser water supply temperature in the chiller; Formulas (21) and (22) indicate that the water flow in the pump should be controlled within a certain range; Formulas (23) and (24) indicates the control range of the fan airflow.

Furthermore, central air conditioning should keep room temperature within an acceptable range for users with the constraint expressed:

TmininTin(t)Tmaxin(25)

Here, Tminin and Tmaxin is the lowest/highest room temperature acceptable to users.

2.2 Energy Storage Model

VPP’s internal converged energy storage model can make a profit through “low price storage and high price discharge” according to external electricity price, improve the VPP income level, and enhance the VPP operation mode flexibility. The equality constraint of energy storage capacity during energy storage system regulation is as follows:

Stess=St1ess+ηchPtchPtdis/ηdis(26)

In the formula, Stess is the energy storage capacity at time t; ηch and ηdis are the charging and discharge efficiency of energy storage at time t; Ptch and Ptdis the charging power and discharge power of the energy storage system at time t.

The main constraints during the energy storage system operation are as follows:

SminStessSmax(27)

0PtchPchmax(28)

0PtdisPdismax(29)

In the formula, Smin and Smax are the lower and upper limit of energy storage capacity; Pchmax and Pdismax the maximum charge and discharge power of energy storage, respectively.

3  Peer-to-Peer Trading Model of Multiple VPP Based on Non-Cooperative Game

Each VPP is different in social characteristics and aggregation source load unit. At the same time, adjacent VPP may have “power surplus”, “power shortage” and “power self-balance” in three states. Therefore, “price” could be used as the driving force for effective resource management of clustering VPPs, to give full play to the flexibility value of VPPs aggregation resources and improve their economic benefits. P2P is an effective means of decentralized trading between VPPs. At a moment, the demand for VPPs trading power is calculated as:

Pz,tex=Pz,tpv+Pz,tdisPz,tchPz,tloadPz,thvac(30)

Pz,tex represents the trading electric quantity of the VPPz. If it is positive, the VPPz is the seller; if it is negative, the VPPz is the buyer. Pz,tpv, Pz,tdis, Pz,tch, Pz,tload and Pz,thvac indicate the photovoltaic output power, energy storage discharge power, energy storage charging power, fixed load, and central air conditioning load of the VPPz at time t.

In addition, in the actual trading process, VPPs can combine the seller VPPs and market operator quotation with their situation to make the choice. There is a certain competition relationship between sellers at the same time, such as the seller VPPs and market operators. Both need to determine the best quotation strategy according to their benefit function to maximize the income. Therefore, this paper introduces a non-cooperative game mechanism to describe the competition between VPP and market operators.

3.1 Non-Cooperative Game Model

The basic form of the general non-cooperative game model is as follows:

G=<Γ;(Bi);(ui)>(31)

In the formula, Γ, Bi and ui are the basic game elements, namely, the game party, game strategy, and utility function, which are specified with the following VPPs trading model:

(1) Game party

In the P2P trading process, the game party is the seller VPP and distribution network at time t. The set of all seller VPPs is marked as Γpro={PRO1,PRO2,,PRON} and the set of market operators is marked as ΓDS={DS}, so the game participants can be summarized as the set ΓΓproΓDS.

(2) Game strategy

(2) For the seller VPPs, its game strategy is the electricity price λm,tpro that it sells to the buyer VPPs; for the operator, because its trading electricity price (namely retail price) with the subordinate VPPs is generally determined, the retail price should not be used as its game strategy. However, P2P trading between VPPs normally needs the support of hardware and software platforms. This service is generally provided by operators. Therefore, the operator’s game strategy is to charge service fees λtds for P2P transactions between VPPs. The upper limit of P2P trading quotation between VPPs is λtpro,max and the upper limit of market operator service fee is λtds,max, then the set of seller VPPs game strategies can be marked as Bpro=[0,λm,tpro,max], and the set of market operator game strategies can be marked as Bds=[0,λtds,max].

(3) Utility function

For seller VPPs, its utility function is the electricity sale income minus relevant cost at time t, which expressed as follows:

um,tpro=um,tp2p+um,tmobum,tserum,tdr(32)

In the formula, um,tp2p, um,tmob, um,tser, um,tdr are the P2P electricity sales revenue, trading revenue with operators, P2P service cost, and air conditioning load regulation cost of the mth seller VPPs. Each part is calculated as follows, respectively:

um,tp2p=λm,tproΔtx=1NxPm,x,tpro(33)

um,tmob=λtbΔtPm,tmo,b(34)

um,tser=λtdsΔtx=1NxPm,x,tpro(35)

um,tdr=φm(TtinTtref)2(36)

In the formulas, Pm,x,tpro is the electricity selling power of seller VPP to the buyer VPPx. Nx is the number of buyer VPPs. λtb is the electricity purchase price of operators, and Pm,tmo,b is the electricity selling power of seller VPP to operators. φm is the coefficient to quantize economic cost and Ttref indicates the reference room temperature which is most comfortable to users.

The utility function of market operators is also its profit in market trading, that is, the retail market profit minus its wholesale electricity cost, which is calculated as follows:

utDS=utmo+utserutda(37)

In the formula, utDS represents the net profit of market operators, and utmo is electricity trading income in the retail market; utser is the service fee charged for P2P trading between VPPs; utda is wholesale electricity price cost. Each part is calculated as follows:

utmo=Δt[λtsm=1NmPm,tmo,sλtbx=1NxPx,tmo,b](38)

utser=2λtdsΔtx=1Nxm=1NmPm,x,tpro(39)

utda=λtdaΔtPt(40)

In the formulas, λts indicates the electricity selling price that market operators sell to buyer VPP. Pm,tmos and Px,tmob are the market operator electricity selling and purchase power. Pt indicates the total power that operators sell to VPPs. λtda is the wholesale market electricity price.

3.2 Induction and Proof of Nash Equilibrium Point

The Nash equilibrium point of the non-cooperative game is defined as: when the system reaches the game equilibrium, changes in either party’s game strategy will not improve its utility function. The strategy of the game equilibrium point is marked as M0. To prove the point is the game Nash equilibrium point, the offset of utility function when the game strategy is unilaterally adjusted needs to be studied. Specifically, the offset scenarios include (1) any seller VPP decreases its P2P quotation; (2) any seller VPP increases its P2P quotation; (3) the market operator decreases the service quotation; (4) the market operator increases its service quotation. In this paper, the Nash equilibrium point is first summarized through two offset scenarios, and then the other two offset scenarios are also proved to meet the Nash equilibrium point definition. Details are demonstrated in Appendix B, and the resulting Nash equilibrium point is as follows:

{λm,tpro=λtb+λts2,m{1,2,,Nm}λtds=λtsλtb2(41)

4  Example Analysis

4.1 Example Description

In this paper, one market operator and three VPPs aggregating different public buildings are used to verify the effectiveness of the established model. VPP1 aggregates two shopping malls, VPP2 aggregates 2 hotels, and VPP3 aggregates 2 office buildings. The basic parameters of these public buildings are shown in Table 1. Considering that the photovoltaic output of 0:00~7:00 and 18:00~24:00 is low, all VPPs are at the state of electricity purchase without P2P trading between each other. This paper only studies the VPPs electricity trading between 8:00 and 17:00. In this period, the predicted photovoltaic power, predicted load power, and outdoor temperature of each VPP are shown in Appendix Figs. C1C3. The calculation of building thermal parameters in public buildings could refer to Reference [24] and the specific parameters of central air conditioning systems could be seen in reference [25]. The electricity purchase price, electricity sale price, and electricity wholesale price of market operators are shown in Appendix Fig. C4. In this paper, GAMS 24.4 software is used to call IPOPT solver to program and solve the model.

images

4.2 Analysis of Example Results

(1) Analysis of public building regulation strategies

Combined with the global optimization model of the central air conditioning system, the controllable potential of VPPs aggregated public buildings is evaluated. The controllable power of the six public buildings is shown in Fig. 3, respectively. It can be found that the VPP3 aggregated two office buildings have the largest load reduction quantity whereas the VPP1 aggregated Shopping mall 1 and VPP2 aggregated Hotel 2 have lower load reduction quantity. It is mainly because, the two office buildings are equipped with units with higher capacity and larger scheduling space. On the other hand, the reference temperature of the two office buildings is higher, hence with a larger temperature adjustment range and larger reducible load.

images

Figure 3: Load reduction results of public buildings

Fig. 4 shows the changes in public building rooms temperature optimized by the flexible regulation strategy proposed in this paper. The predicted average voting index is further used to combine room temperature with comfort [24] and divide the user comfort zone as shown in Fig. 4. It can be seen that after optimization, the room temperature of each building maintains the user comfort zone. And the overall room temperature curve of Office buildings 1 and 2 with higher reference temperature is also higher than that of other public buildings, so as to provide more sufficient load adjustment space.

images

Figure 4: Room temperature regulation results in public buildings

VPPs optimize the overall energy consumption of the air conditioning system by controlling variables, such as cooling water temperature, chilled water temperature, flow speed, and wind speed of the public building air conditioning system, and conducts flexible regulation on the premise of ensuring the user comfort. Taking Hotel 1 as an example, the results of each decision variable of the central air conditioning system of Hotel 1 at different periods are shown in Table 2. As can be seen, when the chilled water temperature is set at about 4.5°C and wind speed is controlled at about 3~4 kg/s, the energy consumption of the Hotel 1 air conditioning system is the lowest.

images

(2) VPPs market trading results considering public building regulation

To verify the effectiveness of the proposed multi-VPPs Peer-to-Peer energy trading method considering the public building’s controllable potential, the following comparative examples are set. In different scenarios, comparisons of the market trading demand of each VPP are shown in Fig. 5.

images

Figure 5: VPP trading requirements in different scenarios

Case 1: The central air conditioning system adopts the constant temperature control strategy without optimizing the air conditioning system;

Case 2: The flexible control strategy proposed in this paper is used to optimize the global central air conditioning load.

As can be seen in Fig. 5, compared with the central air conditioning system with constant temperature control, the flexible control strategy adopted in this paper can greatly improve the VPPs scheduling potential. The VPPs electricity purchase demand is generally reduced and electricity sales are increased. Therefore, VPP’s interaction cost with market operators as well as other VPPs will decrease. Taking t = 9:00 as an example, under the two strategies, the utility function value changes of seller VPP1 with the game strategy are shown in Figs. 6a and 6b, and the utility function value changes of market operators with the game strategy is shown in Figs. 7a and 7b. Therefore, the overall revenue of seller VPP1 in the Case 2 scenario is higher. It is mainly because under this paper’s flexible regulation strategy, the market power level of each VPP has improved and the power sale quantity of seller VPP has increased significantly. Hence, the overall income of seller VPPs also increases.

images

Figure 6: Utility function changes of VPP1 in different scenarios

images

Figure 7: Utility function changes of market operators in different scenarios

Because of flexible regulation of public buildings, the market trading potential of each VPP has also improved and even the exchange of trading roles can be realized, which is demonstrated by the following power trading strategies between VPPs at 12:00, 14:00, and 16:00. The trading strategy is shown in Appendix Fig. D1. As can be seen, at 12:00, because of the large regulation potential of buildings at this time, the market power level of each VPP increases, and the P2P electricity trading quantity between VPPs greatly decreases. At 14:00, after optimization, the market power level of VPP1 greatly increases, buyer VPP changes to seller VPP, the P2P electricity trading quantity between VPP2 and VPP3 increases, and with the market role change, the P2P electricity trading between VPP1 and VPP2 is 0. At 16:00, the controllable potential of VPP1 and VPP2 aggregated buildings reduces whereas the controllable potential of VPP3 aggregated buildings is still large. Therefore, the P2P electricity trading quantity between VPP increases significantly, from 105 to 217.1 kW. As can be seen, it could improve the market competitiveness by accurately evaluating the VPPs market potential before trading, to adopting more active trading strategies in market trading.

(3) Game equilibrium and trading mode analysis

Because of the competitive relationship between seller VPPs and market operators, P2P trading between VPPs does not always occur as disturbed by various influencing factors. Taking the Case 2 scenario at t = 9:00 as an example, the game problem’s Nash equilibrium solutions change with the air conditioning load regulation cost and operator service quotation upper limit, as shown in Figs. 8 and 9.

images

Figure 8: VPP market trading strategy in different scenarios

images

Figure 9: The Nash equilibrium solution when the service quote ceiling is lowered

First, when the air conditioning quantitative cost coefficient increases gradually, it has no impact on the VPPs trading behavior or Nash equilibrium point distribution, and only affects the benefit function of seller VPPs, as shown in Fig. 8. This is mainly because, in the game equilibrium point M0, the quantitative economic cost coefficient of air conditioning load is not regarded as the variable affecting the Nash equilibrium point. Therefore, it will not affect the P2P trading form. It can be inferred that the wholesale electricity price will not impact the VPPs trading behavior and the Nash equilibrium point distribution.

Secondly, when the upper limit of market operator service price quotation decreases, it can be seen that the P2P trading behavior between VPPs changes significantly. With the decrease of service price quotation upper limit, when λtdsmax(λtsλtb)/2, except for P2P trading at the equilibrium point M0, there is only VPP trading with operators and no P2P trading at other points. When λtdsmax<(λtsλtb)/2, P2P trading occurs more easily between VPPs, not only with market operators. Based on this, market operators can quantitatively formulate service fees, which can restrict or facilitate trading between VPPs.

5  Conclusion

This paper proposes a multi-VPP Peer-to-Peer energy source that considers the controllable potential of public buildings, aiming at the problems that the energy consumption characteristics of transaction entities cannot be fully considered in the current VPPs market-oriented transaction process, and the game relationship between transaction entities still needs to be further explored. The trading method, after analysis and research, came to the following conclusions:

(1)   Considering the flexible control of public buildings in the VPPs’ P2P transaction process, it can significantly improve the market competitiveness of each VPP, promote it to adopt a more active transaction strategy in market transactions, and improve their overall income.

(2)   The air conditioning load economic cost coefficient of VPPs and the electricity price in the wholesale market have no substantial impact on the VPP trading mode and Nash equilibrium solution distribution. But the upper limit of operator service quotation will have a relatively large effect on the VPP trading mode. When the service price gradually reduces, P2P trading between VPPs is more likely to occur.

This paper does not consider the network structure of the power system and the power flow of the system. Therefore, the large-scale air-conditioning load participating in the grid regulation model considering the safety and economy of the distribution network needs to be further researched in the future.

Funding Statement: This work was supported by the Technology Project of State Grid Jiangsu Electric Power Co., Ltd., China, under Grant 2021200.

Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest to report regarding the present study.

References

    1. Nosratabadi, S. M., Hooshmand, R. A., Gholipour, E. (2017). A comprehensive review on microgrid and virtual power plant concepts employed for distributed energy resources scheduling in power systems. Renewable & Sustainable Energy Reviews, 67, 341–363. DOI 10.1016/j.rser.2016.09.025. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

    2. Naval, N., Yusta, J. M. (2021). Virtual power plant models and electricity markets–A review. Renewable & Sustainable Energy Reviews, 149(13), 1–13. DOI 10.1016/j.rser.2021.111393. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

    3. Xu, S., Xue, Y., Chang, L. (2021). Review of power system support functions for inverter-based distributed energy resources-standards, control algorithms, and trends. IEEE Open Journal of Power Electronics, 2, 88–105. DOI 10.1109/OJPEL.2021.3056627. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

    4. Zhou, Y., Wei, Z., Sun, G., Cheung, K. W., Zang, H. et al. (2019). Four-level robust model for a virtual power plant in energy and reserve markets. IET Generation, Transmission & Distribution, 13(11), 2036–2043. DOI 10.1049/iet-gtd.2018.5197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

    5. Diana, M. Z., John, G. R. (2017). Opportunities and challenges of mainstreaming distributed energy resources towards the transition to more efficient and resilient energy markets. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 157(10), 112018. DOI 10.1016/j.rser.2021.112018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

    6. Gong, X. (2021). Energy security through a financial lens: Rethinking geopolitics, strategic investment, and governance in China’s global energy expansion. Energy Research & Social Science, 83, 102341. DOI 10.1016/j.erss.2021.102341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

    7. Dai, R., Esmaeilbeigi, R., Charkhgard, H. (2021). The utilization of shared energy storage in energy systems: A comprehensive review. IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, 12(4), 3163–3174. DOI 10.1109/TSG.2021.3061619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

    8. An, L., Duan, J., Chow, M., Duel-Hallen, A. (2019). A distributed and resilient bargaining game for weather-predictive microgrid energy cooperation. IEEE Transactions on Industrial Informatics, 15(8), 4721–4730. DOI 10.1109/TII.2019.2907380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

    9. Han, L., Morstyn, T., McCulloch, M. (2021). Scaling up cooperative game theory-based energy management using prosumer clustering. IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, 12(1), 289–300. DOI 10.1109/TSG.2020.3015088. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  10. Malik, S., Duffy, M., Thakur, S., Hayes, B., Breslin, J. (2022). A priority-based approach for Peer-to-Peer energy trading using cooperative game theory in local energy community. International Journal of Electrical Power & Energy Systems, 137(4), 107865. DOI 10.1016/j.ijepes.2021.107865. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  11. Vespermann, N., Hamacher, T., Kazempour, J. (2021). Access economy for storage in energy communities. IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, 36(3), 2234–2250. DOI 10.1109/TPWRS.2020.3033999. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  12. Chen, L., Liu, N., Li, C., Wang, J. (2021). Peer-to-Peer energy sharing with social attributes: A stochastic leader-follower game approach. IEEE Transactions on Industrial Informatics, 17(4), 2545–2556. DOI 10.1109/TII.2020.2999328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  13. Liu, N., Yu, X., Wang, C., Wang, J. (2017). Energy sharing management for microgrids with PV prosumers: A stackelberg game approach. IEEE Transactions on Industrial Informatics, 13(3), 1088–1098. DOI 10.1109/TII.2017.2654302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  14. Cui, S., Wang, Y., Shi, Y., Xiao, J. (2020). A new and fair peer-to-peer energy sharing framework for energy buildings. IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, 11(5), 3817–3826. DOI 10.1109/TSG.2020.2986337. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  15. Paudel, A., Chaudhari, K., Long, C., Gooi, H. B. (2019). Peer-to-Peer energy trading in a prosumer-based community microgrid: A game-theoretic model. IEEE Transactions on Industrial Electronics, 66(8), 6087–6097. DOI 10.1109/TIE.2018.2874578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  16. Sun, G., Qian, W., Huang, W., Wei, Z., Zang, H. et al. (2019). Optimal dispatch game model for virtual power plant considering security of distribution network. Electric Power Automation Equipment, 39(5), 7–14. DOI 10.16081/j.issn.1006-6047.2019.05.002. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  17. Ge, S., Li, J., Liu, H., He, X., Shen, K. (2021). Peer-to-Peer energy trading method for multiple microgrids considering characteristics of smart building. Automation of Electric Power Systems, 45(6), 203–214. DOI 10.7500/AEPS20200330004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  18. Luthander, R., Widen, J., Nilsson, D., Palm, J. (2015). Photovoltaic self-consumption in buildings: A review. Applied Energy, 142(10), 80–94. DOI 10.1016/j.apenergy.2014.12.028. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  19. Moradi, J., Shahinzadeh, H., Khandan, A., Moazzami, A. (2017). A profitability investigation into the collaborative operation of wind and underwater compressed air energy storage units in the spot market. Energy, 141(3), 1779–1794. DOI 10.1016/j.energy.2017.11.088. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  20. Adhikari, R., Pipattanasomporn, M., Rahman, S. (2020). Heuristic algorithms for aggregated HVAC control via smart thermostats for regulation service. IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, 11(3), 2023–2032. DOI 10.1109/TSG.2019.2946170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  21. Ranzi, G., Kong, W., Dong, Y., Wang, F. (2018). Coordinated residential energy resource scheduling with vehicle-to-home and high photovoltaic penetrations. IET Renewable Power Generation, 148(6), 1–15. DOI 10.1049/iet-rpg.2017.0485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  22. Wang, H., Hu, S. (2009). Analysis on the applicability of PMV thermal comfort model. Building Science, 25(6). DOI 10.13614/j.cnki.11-1962/tu.2009.06.013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  23. Feng, W., Wei, Z., Sun, G., Zhou, Y., Zang, H. et al. (2020). A conditional value-at-risk-based dispatch approach for the energy management of smart buildings with HVAC systems. Electric Power Systems Research, 188, 106535. DOI 10.1016/j.epsr.2020.106535. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  24. Sun, G., Qian, W., Huang, W., Xu, Z., Wei, Z. et al. (2019). Stochastic adaptive robust dispatch for virtual power plants using the binding scenario identification approach. Energies, 12(10), 1918. DOI 10.3390/en12101918. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

  25. Yao, Y., Chen, J. (2010). Global optimization of a central air-conditioning system using decomposition-coordination method. Energy and Buildings, 42(5), 570–583. DOI 10.1016/j.enbuild.2009.10.027. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

Appendix A

images

Figure A1: Schematic diagram of the central air-conditioning circulation system

Appendix B

(1) The market operator raises the service quotation

First, assuming the market operator raises the service quotation at the game equilibrium point M0 moment, there is λm,tpro+λtdsl>λm,tpro+λtds0, that is to say, the electricity purchase cost of any buyer VPP from operators is lower than from seller VPP. Therefore, buyer VPP will not trade with seller VPP and Pm,x,tprol=0 is obtained. Subtract the utility function, then:

utDSlutDS0=Δt[λts(m=1NmPm,tmoblm=1NmPm,tmob0)λtb(x=1NxPx,tmos0x=1NxPx,tmosl)+ 2λtdslx=1Nxm=1NmPm,xprol2λtds0x=1Nxm=1NmPm,x,tpro0](B1)

Through the power balance of all seller/seller VPP, the following is obtained:

m=1Nmx=1NxPm,x,tpro=m=1NmPm,texm=1NmPm,tmob,m=1Nmx=1NxPm,x,tpro+x=1NxPx,tmos=x=1NxPx,tex(B2)

Substitute Eq. (B2) into Eq. (B1) to further simplify:

utDSlutDS0=Δt[(λtbλts)m=1Nmx=1NxPm,x,tpro02λtds0m=1Nmx=1NxPm,x,tpro0=(λtsλtb2λtds0)m=1Nmx=1NxPm,x,tpro0](B3)

Because Pm,x,tpro0 is a non-zero term, when λtsλtb2λtds0=0, the condition of the game equilibrium point is met.

(2) Any seller VPP reduces its P2P quotation

Further, assuming any seller VPP suddenly reduces its P2P trading quotation and deducts the utility function, there is:

um,tpro1um,tpro0=Δt[λm,tpro1x=1NxPm,x,tpro1+λtbPm,tmob1λtdsx=1NxPm,x,tpro1λm,tpro0x=1NxPm,x,tpro0λtbPm,tmob0+λtdsx=1NxPm,x,tpro0](B4)

Through the VPP power balance, the following is obtained:

x=1NxPm,x,tpro+Pm,tmob=Pm,tex,m=1NmPm,x,tpro+Px,tmos=Px,tex(B5)

Substitute Eq. (B5) into Eq. (B4), extract similar terms and simplify, the following is acquired:

um,tpro1um,tpro0=(λm,tpro1λtbλtds)Δtx=1NxPm,x,tpro1(λm,tpro0λtbλtds)Δtx=1NxPm,x,tpro1(B6)

Because λtpro1λtpro0=(λtb0+λts0)/2, the above formula can be further simplified as:

um,tpro1um,tpro0(λm,tpro0λtbλtds)Δt(x=1NxPm,x,tpro1x=1NxPm,x,tpro0)(B7)

To make um,tpro1um,tpro00, set λm,tpro0λtbλtds=0 and substitute the condition λtbλts2λtds0=0, then 2λm,tpro0λtbλts=0 is obtained. Through the above two assumptions, the game equilibrium point can be deduced as:

{λm,tpro=λtb+λts2,m{1,2,,Nm}λtds=λtbλts2(B8)

The other two game equilibrium point offset scenarios, such as any seller VPP raising its P2P quotation or market operator reducing its service quotation, still meet the game equilibrium point conditions, specifically proved as follows.

(3) Any seller VPP raises its P2P quotation

When any seller VPP raises its P2P trading quotation, λtpro1>λtpro0=(λtb0+λts0)/2, that is, the electricity purchase cost of any buyer VPP from seller VPP is higher than that from other VPP. Besides,

λtpro1+λtds>λtpro0+λtds=(λtb0λts0)/2+(λtb0+λts0)/2=λts0(B9)

Therefore, the electricity purchase cost of any buyer VPP from seller VPPl is also higher than that from direct trading with operators. No VPP will choose to trade with seller VPP, that is Pm,x,tprol=0. Referring to the above simplification process, there is:

um,tpro1um,tpro0=(λm,tpro1λtbλtds)Δtx=1NxPm,x,tpro1(λm,tpro0λtbλtds)Δtx=1NxPm,x,tpro1=0(B10)

Then, there is um,tpro1um,tpro0=0, that is, any seller VPP’s rise in the quotation will not increase the utility function.

(4) The market operator lowers its service quotation

When the market operator lowers its service quotation, λm,tpro+λtdsl<λm,tpro+λtds0=λts, that is, the trading cost between buyer VPP and operators is higher than that with seller VPP. Therefore, buyer VPP tends to trade with seller VPP, that is, similar to the trading mode at the game equilibrium point M0. The following equation is obtained:

m=1NmPm,tmobl=m=1NmPm,tmob0,x=1NxPx,tmosl=m=1NmPx,tmos0,x=1Nxm=1NmPm,x,tprol=x=1Nxm=1NmPm,x,tpro0(B11)

Referring to the simplification process of Eqs. (B4)–(B7), there is:

utDSlutDS0=λtsΔt(m=1NmPm,tmoblm=1NmPxmob0)+λtbΔt(x=1NxPxmos0x=1NxPxmosl)+2λtdslΔtx=1Nxm=1NmPm,x,tprol2λtds0Δtx=1Nxm=1NmPm,x,tpro0=2(λtdslλtds0)x=1Nxm=1NmPm,xprol0(B12)

Therefore, utDSlutDS00, that is, when market operators lower the service quotations, it will not increase the utility function.

To sum up, the above four-game strategy offset scenarios will not increase the corresponding utility function value of the game party. Combined with the definition of pure strategy Nash equilibrium, it can be proved that M0 is the Nash equilibrium point of the game model.

Appendix C

images

Figure C1: Photovoltaic output of each VPP

images

Figure C2: Predicted value of each VPP load

images

Figure C3: Outdoor temperature curve

images

Figure C4: Market trading electricity price

Appendix D

images

Figure D1: VPP market trading strategy in different scenarios


Cite This Article

APA Style
Bai, J., Zhou, H., Xu, Z., Zhong, Y. (2023). Peer-to-peer energy trading method of multi-virtual power plants based on non-cooperative game. Energy Engineering, 120(5), 1163-1183. https://doi.org/10.32604/ee.2023.025553
Vancouver Style
Bai J, Zhou H, Xu Z, Zhong Y. Peer-to-peer energy trading method of multi-virtual power plants based on non-cooperative game. Energ Eng. 2023;120(5):1163-1183 https://doi.org/10.32604/ee.2023.025553
IEEE Style
J. Bai, H. Zhou, Z. Xu, and Y. Zhong, “Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading Method of Multi-Virtual Power Plants Based on Non-Cooperative Game,” Energ. Eng., vol. 120, no. 5, pp. 1163-1183, 2023. https://doi.org/10.32604/ee.2023.025553


cc Copyright © 2023 The Author(s). Published by Tech Science Press.
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License , which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
  • 880

    View

  • 577

    Download

  • 0

    Like

Share Link