[BACK]
Computer Systems Science & Engineering
DOI:10.32604/csse.2021.016506
images
Article

External Incentive Mechanism Research on Knowledge Cooperation-Sharing in the Chinese Creative Industry Cluster

Changchun Gao1, Shiyu Liu1,*, Chenhui Yu1 and Peng Guo2

1Sun Glorious School of Business, Donghua University, Shanghai, 200051, China
2Unviersity Malaysia Sabah, Kota Kinabalu, Malaysia
*Corresponding Author: Shiyu Liu. Email: Saber0471@163.com
Received: 04 January 2021; Accepted: 28 February 2021

Abstract: The creative industry is a knowledge-based industry, but it is difficult and complex to create knowledge for enterprises. The principle of cooperation-sharing posits that companies’ limited resources prohibit them from gaining a competitive advantage in all business areas. Therefore, cooperation-sharing can help businesses overcome this hurdle. Cooperation-sharing expedites economic development, breaks the barrier of independent knowledge creation, and enhances resource utilization. However, the effectiveness and stability of knowledge cooperation-sharing are key problems facing governments and other regulators. This study can help regulators promote honesty in enterprise cooperation-sharing. Based on the hypothesis of bounded rationality, the evolutionary game theory was used to construct the “Enterprises–Informal Institutions–Government” tripartite game matrix. Next, based on this game matrix, a simulation analysis method was used to analyze the effects of external incentives on the stability of evolutionary strategies. The analysis shows that the strategic choice of the “Enterprises–Informal Institutions–Government” tripartite game could be affected by the initial state strategy choices of the other two players, but more influential were the cost and external incentive levels of the game players. The results indicate that the government and informal institutions should regulate enterprises with a rational external incentive mechanism that boosts the enterprises’ incentive to cooperate honestly. Thus, an effective external incentive mechanism can significantly improve the probability of enterprises behaving honestly in cooperation-sharing and promote the development of the creative industry.

Keywords: Creative industry; knowledge sharing; evolutionary game; external incentives

1  Background

China has experienced a difficult period of economic structural adjustment since the outbreak of the novel coronavirus in 2019. The traditional industry is over-capacity, and the demographic dividends, which refer to the economic growth that results from the changing age of a country’s population, have decreased, making exportation difficult. As such, the prior development model is no longer applicable to the current Chinese economy. To break through the bottlenecks and constraints of the present economic development, the Chinese government has proposed some guidelines and policies. One of these policies involves the internal circular economy model [1] and the vigorous development of creative industries. The internal circular economy model encourages citizens to set up stalls, which helps them increase profits during a crisis such as the pandemic, as daily work is less available. Developing the creative industry is a signal that the Chinese government is trying to change the existing economic system into a high-knowledge economy. Knowledge is the most valuable strategic resource because it helps companies manufacture more products [2], enables the government to improve the market economy mechanism [3], and accelerates the development of the green economy by reducing pollution and strengthening sustainable development.

The creative industry has distinct characteristics. Its high integration and diversity of knowledge promote knowledge transfer to different fields [4], and restructure the knowledge system for companies and their products. In the early years of the creative industry’s growth, most people believed that the gathering of creative workers formed creative settlements, provided an effective platform for innovative products, and laid a foundation for further expansion [5]. With its evolution and continuous social development, the gathering of creative workers transformed into the gathering of creative enterprises, and gradually formed creative clusters [6,7]. Creative clusters are constructed under a professional organizational structure in a geographical space, thus helping creative enterprises enhance industrial cohesion and improve their ability to redistribute industrial resources [8]. The creative industry has gradually developed a network with knowledge as its core, the clusters as the carrier, and the enterprises as the nodes [9,10]. On this basis, knowledge transfer, sharing, and cooperation are the three main ways to boost the creative industries’ process and the creative economy’s development. With the increasing complexity and diversity of the economic society, enterprises must create new competitive advantages through innovation. Some researchers propose the use of non-cooperative games to optimize resource scheduling [11,12], gather all the resources, or reject cooperation to avoid the risk of losses. However, in the current situation, limited resources and high costs are barriers to enterprise innovation. Cooperation-sharing [13] has become a significant choice for enterprises to develop, innovate, and establish advantages. It can reduce innovation costs and technical requirements, lower the risk of independent innovation, and shorten the innovation cycle. Cooperation-sharing helps enterprises engage with markets and promotes resource integration and utilization in the whole value chain. Eventually, it enables enterprises to reach a higher level [14].

Cooperation-sharing is a win-win option to help enterprises overcome difficulties. However, it may lead to a leakage of core knowledge and cause enterprises to suffer more losses [15]. Thus, the choice of whether to conduct cooperation-sharing is of great significance to enterprises. Cooperation-sharing is a joint innovation mode [16] in which both sides of the cooperation represent the main body of innovation at the same time, take common interests as the goal, jointly conduct knowledge input, and bear costs and risks (as well as the innovation results). According to research by Zhou et al. [17] and Yang et al. [18], the distance between partners in different dimensions, such as the social status of potential partners, goodwill, compatibility with their enterprises, and differences in the working level between the two parties, directly affects cooperation-sharing behavior. Even the geographical and technical distances have different degrees of impact on cooperation-sharing. Diversified external incentives also have a crucial influence on cooperation-sharing, and the external subsidies can effectively improve the efficiency and enthusiasm of cooperation-sharing [19]. According to Wu’s research [20], the essence of cooperation-sharing innovation behavior is to accelerate the flow and transformation of knowledge. Different characteristics of knowledge have different influences on cooperation-sharing, such as the different characteristics of knowledge, the degree of trust, the heterogeneity of knowledge, and the cost of knowledge sharing [21]. Moreover, knowledge characteristics, degree of trust, knowledge heterogeneity, knowledge sharing cost, and other factors add to the difficulties of enterprises’ cooperation-sharing behavior. However, if the characteristics are fully designated, the cooperation process may be improved. For example, full sharing of explicit knowledge and tacit knowledge maximizes the innovation rate and quality of the enterprises. Similarly, the geographical location, cultural differences, religious beliefs, and other factors may lead to conflicts in cooperation-sharing behavior, which reduces the cooperation probability and the effectiveness of cooperation-sharing. Both sides of cooperation-sharing face the leakage or transfer of the shared knowledge to a third party [22,23]. If there is a relatively high degree of cooperation, the risk of knowledge loss or leakage will be higher when there is more shared knowledge, higher knowledge relevance, and a higher acceptance level of both sides.

In the current literature, we found detailed analyses and discussions on the objectives, influencing factors, corresponding risks, and incentives of enterprise knowledge cooperation-sharing. However, there has been little research on enterprise cooperation under dual supervision to date. We examined the enterprises in the creative industry cluster, the government, and informal institutions as players and established a tripartite cooperation game model with the duplication of supervision by the government and informal institutions. We then used the evolutionary game theory to analyze enterprises’ strategy about knowledge cooperation-sharing in the creative industry cluster. We then conducted a numerical simulation through MATLAB to explain enterprises’ behavior in the process of cooperation-sharing. This study provides guidance to creative enterprises for facilitating cooperation and to the government and informal institutions for regulating enterprises during cooperation-sharing.

2  Research Hypothesis

According to the assumption of bounded rationality in the evolutionary game, bounded rational agents cannot accurately predict their payoff function and make the most effective strategy choice. Thus, decision-makers need to simulate and learn the revenue strategy through repeated experiments and then find an effective and stable equilibrium state to support their decision-making. By analyzing the decision-making equilibrium of each participant to set up a payment function, we can get the corresponding copy dynamics and draw a conclusion. The creative industry cluster has sociality. When enterprises start to cooperate and share knowledge, they are social participants with bounded rationality. In the creative industry, the policies issued by the government serve as formal constraints. Also, some informal institutions, such as industry associations, chambers of commerce, and industrial alliances, provide regulatory and supervisory functions other than formal constraints for the operation of creative industry clusters and enterprise exchanges and cooperation. We label such constraints implicit contracts [24].

Hypothesis 1: When enterprises cooperate and share knowledge, there are benefits to the enterprises and government. When informal institutions can provide effective implicit contracts, informal institutions can also derive some economic benefits. Suppose Gi ( i=1,2,3,4) is the revenue of the government in the game. According to the implicit contract of informal institutions and whether enterprises in the cluster are honest, the government offers different benefits. Under the influence of an effective implicit contract, informal organizations get the corresponding benefits. Suppose Qi(i=1,2,3,4) is the income of enterprises in creative industries. Enterprises’ profits depend on whether the government regulates and whether the implicit contract of the informal institutions is binding.

Hypothesis 2: In the evolutionary game system, the decision-making of each participant may come with different costs. When the government decides to regulate the cluster, it needs some cost; c1 is the cost for the supervision of the enterprises, and c2 is the cost for promoting and maintaining the operation of informal institutions. The informal institutions can monitor enterprises with a cost, c3 , under the condition of a workable implicit contract. If enterprises are honest during knowledge cooperation-sharing, they must invest in sharing the cost, c4 . If the enterprises are dishonest or experience a betrayal of cooperation, the cost of cooperation-sharing will be reduced; the cost is assumed to be Jc4 ( 0<J<1 ). During the knowledge cooperation-sharing process, the enterprises also face the risk of knowledge leakage, assuming that the possible cost of the knowledge leakage is c5 ( ci>=0,i=0,1,5) .

Hypothesis 3: Incentive mechanism. If the informal institutions can ensure that the implicit contract is implemented effectively in the market, the government will reward the informal institutions with certain benefits. Suppose the reward is D(D>0) . Assuming there is a subsidy provided by the government that is based on the cost of cooperation-sharing with a proportion coefficient, φ , if the enterprise can be honest in cooperation-sharing, the subsidy, φc4 , will be given to the enterprise. Similarly, under the background of government regulation, the enterprises in the cluster need to pay a certain fine to the government, P(P>0) . In the case of the informal institutions supervising the cluster enterprises, if the cluster enterprises do not fulfill the corresponding integrity standards, the enterprises should pay a fine not only to the government, but also to the informal institutions M(M>0) .

Hypothesis 4: Suppose that the collaboration coefficient of cooperation-sharing among enterprises in the cluster is α(α>1) . Assume that β is the risk coefficient of knowledge cooperation-sharing, which is related to the knowledge leakage cost, c5 . So, the possible cost of knowledge leakage of enterprises is β * c5(1>β>0,c5>0) .

According to the above hypothesis, from the government’s perspective, when the government regulates the creative industry cluster, and the government pays the corresponding control cost and obtains certain economic benefits. It provides a cost subsidy to the enterprises that maintain the integrity of the knowledge cooperation-sharing behavior and fines the enterprises that fail to maintain honesty in the cooperation. When informal institutions effectively supervise the enterprises in the cluster, ensure the smooth implementation of the implicit contract, and pay a supervision cost, the informal institution gains certain benefits from the government. If the informal institutions do not supervise and guarantee the implicit contract implementation, the informal institutions will not pay any costs or get any benefits. If the enterprises are honest in knowledge cooperation-sharing, they will obtain benefits and get the cost subsidies. However, if the enterprise cannot be honest, or betray others in the process of knowledge cooperation-sharing, the cost of knowledge cooperation-sharing will be reduced, but it will pay a fine to the government regulator and the informal institution supervisor.

3  Model Establishment and Analysis

According to the above hypothesis, the behavior probability of the present parties in the game is as follows: cluster enterprises: honest-( y) , dishonest- (1y) ; government: regulation- (x) , no regulation- (1x) ; informal institutions: supervision- (z) , and no supervision- (1z) . The game payment matrix was established, as shown in Tab. 1.

Table 1: Tripartite game matrix of enterprises, informal organizations, and governments in creative industry clusters. *I stands for the Informal Institution Supervision

images

By analyzing the assumption and combing the matrix, we could obtain the payoff function of each player in different situations, as well as the corresponding strategy probability and the strategy set of each function, as shown in Tab. 2.

Table 2: Three-party game payment function and strategy set of enterprises, informal organizations, and governments in creative industry clusters

images

3.1 The Government’s Expected Return Function, Evolution Strategy, and Stability Analysis in the Three-party Game

Assuming that Gz1 is the revenue function when the government chooses regulation, according to the expected revenue equation of the game, we could get

Gz1=zy(G1c1c2Dφc4)+z(1y)(G2c1c2D+P)+(1z)y(G3c1c2φc4)+(1z)(1y)(G4c1c2+P). (1)

Assuming that Gz2 is the income function when the government chooses not to regulate, according to the expected income equation of the game, we could get

Gz2=yzG1+(1y)zG2+(1z)yG3+(1z)(1y)G4. (2)

Assuming that Gz3 is the average government revenue, according to the above Gz1 , Gz2 was used to get the government’s average revenue:

Gz3=xGz1+(1x)Gz2, (3)

Gz3=x(zy(G1c1c2Dφc4)+z(1y)(G2c1c2D+P)+(1z)y(G3c1c2φc4)+(1z)(1y)(G4c1c2+P))+(1x)(yzG1+(1y)zG2+(1z)yG3+(1z)(1y)G4). (4)

According to the replication dynamic equation of the evolutionary game, the government’s replication dynamic equation could be obtained:

G(x)=dxdt=x(Gz1Gz3), (5)

G(x)=dxdt=x(φc4y+Dz+PyP+c1+c2)(1+x). (6)

If y0=(P+c1+c2Dz)φc4P , as the parameter was not set, we assumed that (P+c1+c2Dz)φc4P>0 . If y=y0 , G(x)=0 , which means that all states were stable. If yy0 , G(x)=0 , we could get two stable points x=0,x=1 . dG(x)dx=(2x1) *( φc4y+Dz+PyP+c1+c2) . According to the evolutionary stabilization strategy (ESS), G(x)<0 . In this case, when y>y0 , if x=0 , dG(x)dx<0 . If x=1 , dG(x)dx>0 . So, x=0 was the government’s evolutionary stability strategy in this situation. In the same way, when y<y0 , if x=0 , dG(x)dx>0 . If x=1 , dG(x)dx<0 . So, x=1 was the government’s ESS in this situation. Through the above analysis, a dynamic chart of the government’s strategy evolution was obtained, as shown in Fig. 1.

images

Figure 1: Dynamic evolution of the government’s regulation strategy

In Fig. 1, the shadowy area divides the whole space into two parts: the upper part of the space, A1, and the lower part, A2. When the initial strategic state of the government was in space A1, the government’s regulation on the enterprises and the informal institution in the creative cluster was invalid because when y>y0,x=0 was the equilibrium. Whether or not the government chose to regulate, the final strategy choice tended to be unregulated. If the government’s initial strategy state of the government was in space A2, x=1 was the equilibrium point, which indicated that the government’s regulation of enterprises and informal institutions in the creative industry cluster was effective. Whether or not the government regulated, the final strategy choice was close to the regulation strategy. According to Eq. (6) and y0=(P+c1+c2Dz)φc4P , the higher the level of the government’s rewards and punishments to the informal institutions and enterprises in the cluster, the smaller y. At this time, the volume of space A2 was continuously compressed, giving the government a greater probability of being in the A1 space and therefore being more unregulated. Similarly, if the cost of government regulation was higher, the corresponding A2 space was smaller, and the government was less inclined to regulate.

3.2 The Expected Return Function, Evolution Strategy, and Stability Analysis of Informal Institutions in Tripartite Game

Suppose that Kz1 is the income function of the informal institutions when they chose to supervise. Then, according to the expected return equation of the game, we could get the following result:

Kz1=xy(I+Dc3)+x(1y)(I+D+Mc3)+(1x)y(Ic3)+(1x)(1y)(Ic3+M). (7)

Suppose Kz2 is the revenue function of the informal institutions when they chose to supervise. Then, according to the expected return equation of the game, we could get the following result:

Kz2=xy0+(1y)x0+(1x)y0+(1x)(1y)0. (8)

Suppose Kz3 is the average income of the informal institutions. According to the Kz1 , Kz2 , we could get the average income of the informal institutions:

Kz3=zKz1+(1z)Kz2, (9)

Kz3=z(xy(I+Dc3)+x(1y)(I+D+Mc3)+(1x)y(Ic3)+(1x)(1y)(Ic3+M))+(1z)(xy0+(1y)x0+(1x)y0+(1x)(1y)0).

According to the replication dynamic equation of evolutionary game, the replication dynamic equation of informal institutions could be obtained:

K(z)=dzdt=z(Kz1Kz3), (11)

K(z)=dzdt=z(1z)(DxyM+m+Ic3). (12)

If x0=yMMI+c3D , yMMI+c3D>0 . If x0=x , K(z)=0 . In any case, all states could be regarded as stable states. When x0x , if K(z)=0 , z=1orz=0 . When x0x , there were two equilibrium points: z=1,z=0 . According to the ESS rule, we could get the differential equation of K(z):dK(z)dz=(12z)(DxyM+m+Ic3) . If x>x0 , and when z=0 , we could get dK(z)dz>0 ; when z=1 , we could get dK(z)dz<0 . Under the ESS condition, K(Z)<0 had to be satisfied, so, when x>x0 , z=1 was the evolutionary stabilization strategy. If x<x0 , and when z=0 , we could get dK(z)dz<0 ; when z=1 , we could get dK(z)dz>0 . Under the ESS condition, K(Z)<0 had to be satisfied, so when x<x0 , z=0 was the evolutionary stabilization strategy. Through the analysis above, the dynamic chart of informal institutions’ strategy evolution was obtained, as shown in Fig. 2.

images

Figure 2: Dynamic evolution of the informal institutions’ regulation strategy

In Fig. 2, the shadowy area divides the whole space into two parts: the left part, B1, and the right part, B2. When the initial strategic state of the informal institutions was in space B1, the information institutions’ regulation on the enterprises in the creative cluster was effective, and when x>x0 , z=1 was the equilibrium point for the informal institution. Due to the equilibrium point in the system, whether or not the informal institutions were regulated, the strategy tended to be the supervision strategy. When the initial strategic state of the informal institutions was in space B2, the regulation of the informal institutions was invalid. Moreover, when x<x0 , the initial strategic state of the informal institutions was in space B2; in this situation, the strategy constantly tended to be the non-supervision strategy, and the evolutionary stabilization strategy was z=0 . According to x0=yMMI+c3D and Eq. (12), the supervision strategy and the supervision cost were related to the benefit of the supervision strategy and the subsidy from the government. If the supervision cost increased, x0 rose, and the space B1 shrank, then there was a constant tendency towards non-supervision of informal institutions. If there was an increase in the government subsidy, enterprise fines of the violations, and the profit of the supervision, then x0 went down, the space B2 shrank, and the informal institutions chose to supervise to obtain more benefits.

3.3 The Enterprises’ Expected Return Function, Evolution Strategy, and Stability Analysis in the Three-party Game

Suppose Ez1 is the payoff function of the enterprises being honest during sharing and cooperation. According to the payoff function in the evolution game, we could get the following:

Ez1=xz(αQ1c4βc5+φc4)+x(1z)(αQ3c4βc5+φc4)+(1x)z(αQ2c4βc5)+(1x)(1z)(αQ4c4βc5). (13)

Suppose Ez2 is the payoff function of the enterprises being dishonest during sharing and cooperation. According to the payoff function in the evolution game, we could get the following:

Ez2=xz(αQ1Jc4PM)+(1z)x(αQ3Jc4P)+(1x)z(αQ2Jc4M)+(1x)(1z)(αQ4Jc4). (14)

Suppose Ez3 is the average payoff of the enterprises in the cluster. According to the Ez1,Ez2 , we could get the average payoff function of the enterprises in the cluster:

Ez3=yEz1+(1y)Ez2, (15)

Ez3=y(xz(αQ1c4βc5+φc4)+x(1z)(αQ3c4βc5+φc4)+(1x)z(αQ2c4βc5)+(1x)(1z)(αQ4c4βc5))+(1y)(xz(αQ1Jc4PM)+(1z)x(αQ3Jc4P)+(1x)z(αQ2Jc4M)+(1x)(1z)(αQ4Jc4). (16)

According to the replication dynamic equation of evolutionary game, the enterprises’ replication dynamic equation could be obtained:

E(y)=dydt=y(Ez1Ez3), (17)

E(y)=dydt=y(1y)(φc4x+Mz+Pxβc5+Jc4c4). (18)

When z0=c4Px+βc5Jc4φc4xM , suppose that c4Px+βc5Jc4φc4xM>0 . If z0=z , E(y)=0 , which means that in any situation, all states could be considered as stable states. Further, when z0z , if E(y)=0 , we could get y=1,y=0 . So, when z0z , the equilibrium points were y=1,y=0 . According to the ESS rules, the stable evolutionary strategy must satisfy the condition of E(y)<0 :

dE(y)dy=(12y)(φc4x+Mz+Pxβc5+Jc4c4). (19)

If z>z0 , when y=0 , dE(y)dy>0 ; when y=1 , dE(y)dy<0 . So, y=1 was the evolutionarily stable strategy of enterprises in the cluster. Similarly, if z<z0 , when y=0 , dE(y)dy<0 ; when y=1 , dE(y)dy>0 . Here, y=0 was the evolutionary stability strategy of enterprises in the cluster. According to all the analyses above, we could obtain the figure of the dynamic evolution of the enterprises’ strategy.

In Fig. 3, the shadowy area divides the whole space into two parts: the upper part, C1, and the lower part, C2. If the initial strategy of enterprises was stated in the space C1, z>z0 . As the analysis before showed, when z>z0 , the evolutionary stable strategy was y=1 . So, in this situation, whether or not the enterprises were honest during the sharing and cooperation, the final decision for the enterprises was to be honest. Similarly, when the enterprises’ initial strategy was stated in the space C2, the enterprises always chose to be dishonest in the sharing and cooperation. According to Eq. (19) and z0=c4Px+βc5Jc4φc4xM , when the enterprise faced a higher fine for being dishonest, the C2 space shrank, and the probability of enterprises being dishonest was lower. If both the sharing and leakage cost less, the space C2 also shrank, which means the enterprises had a higher probability of being honest during knowledge sharing and cooperation. Similarly, if the sharing cost and leakage cost were much higher than the enterprises’ dishonesty fine by the government and informal institutions, the space C2 was larger and pushed the enterprises to be dishonest with a higher probability.

images

Figure 3: Dynamic evolution of the enterprises’ strategy

4  Numerical Simulation

By deducting the replicator dynamics function of each player, we could get the following equations:

G(x)=dxdt=x(φc4y+Dz+PyP+c1+c2)(1+x), (20)

K(z)=dzdt=z(1z)(DxyM+m+Ic3), (21)

E(y)=dydt=y(1y)(φc4x+Mz+Pxβc5+Jc4c4). (22)

By analyzing the three equations, we found out that the evolution of the dynamic strategy was related to the cost of different players, the reward, and the punishments from the supervisors.

Hypothesis 5: According to the parameters required in the replication dynamics, based on bounded rationality and consultation with experts, we made assumptions about the required parameters: c1=15,c2=0.5,c3=4.5,c4=1.2,c5=1.5,I=3,beta=0.1,J=0.2,Phi=0.5 . Suppose that M,D,andP are in a small interval. M[0,0.55],D[0,1.5],P[0,0.15] , which means that the government’s financial support for informal institutions is less, and the government and informal institutions face a lower punishment for dishonesty. Also, assume that the initial strategy, x0=0.5,y0=0.9,andz0=0.5 . We could get the dynamic strategy evolution diagram of the three parties in the game shown in Fig. 4.

images

Figure 4: Simulation of the dynamic strategy evolution of enterprises, informal institutions, and governments (1)

The government’s replication dynamic equation is composed of the cost and subsidy, so the government showed a change in strategy that tended to be unregulated. When the government was unwilling to supervise, the informal institutions did not derive benefit D from the government, which reduced the desire of the informal institutions to supervise the cooperation. When the government and the informal institution established a low-level punishment for being dishonest, the supervision income, I , and the fine, M , paid by the enterprises to the informal institutions, could not meet the supervising cost, c3 . Therefore, the informal institutions succumbed to supervising enterprises. Enterprises tended to be dishonest during knowledge sharing and cooperation. When the external incentive level was low, the enterprises were more inclined to seek benefits for themselves by being dishonest in cooperation-sharing, so the low external incentive level led enterprises to be unwilling to cooperate honestly.

Hypothesis 6: Based on bounded rationality and consultation with experts, the required parameters are assumed. Assume c1=1.5,c2=0.5,c3=3.5,c4=1.2,c5=1.5,I=3,beta=0.1,J=0.2,Phi=0.5 . Suppose that M,D,andP are in a large interval, and M[10,12],D[1.6,2.5],P[2.15,3.25] . We used all the data to get the simulation results shown in Fig. 5.

images

Figure 5: Simulation of the dynamic strategy evolution of enterprises, informal institutions, and governments (2)

The government’s replicator dynamics function is composed of the cost and subsidy, so the government showed a change in strategy that tended to be unregulated. However, because of the high penalty amount, the enterprises could not reduce the cost and improve the profit through the dishonest cooperation-sharing behavior. Thus, the enterprise tended to cooperate honestly. As the enterprises could not fully be honest in the cooperation, the higher penalty amount made the informal institutions profitable. At the beginning stage, informal institutions wanted to obtain fines from dishonest enterprises, which improved benefits. Therefore, during a period at the beginning of the simulation, informal institutions had a process that was inclined toward supervision. However, in the later stage, enterprises were honest in cooperation-sharing, so informal institutions gradually opted not to supervise. Therefore, with the same cost level of cooperation-sharing, a higher level of external incentives could help enterprises in the cluster to cooperate and share honestly.

Hypothesis 7: Based on bounded rationality and consultation with experts, some required parameters are assumed. Suppose that M,D,andP are in a large interval and M[10,12],D[1.6,2.5],andP[2.15,3.25] . We can assume that c1=1.5,c2=0.5,c3=3.5,c4=12,c5=15,I=3,beta=0.1,J=0.2,andΦ=0.5 . Players have the same probability of being honest or not and to supervise or not, as x0=0.5,y0=0.5,andz0=0.5 . We used all the data to get the simulation results shown in Fig. 6.

images

Figure 6: Simulation of dynamic strategy evolution of enterprises, informal institutions, and governments (3)

Wihtin Hypothesis 7, the cooperating cost and knowledge leakage cost were related more closely than in Hypothesis 6. From the government’s perspective, the cost control issue led the government not to regulate. Moreover, the high operating cost made it difficult for enterprises to continue being honest in cooperation-sharing. In the face of high operating costs, enterprises can save many costs if they are dishonest. As such, although the punishment level was high, compared with the high cost that could be saved by being dishonest, enterprises preferred to be dishonest or betray the cooperation-sharing. Due to the high costs, the enterprises always chose to be dishonest in the cooperation-sharing, so the informal institutions spared no effort to supervise enterprises and obtain fines from them to improve income. In the case of excessive cost, if the external incentive failed to cover the loss caused by the cost, even if facing the problem of penalty, the enterprises still chose the dishonest cooperation-sharing behavior to save costs for themselves.

Hypothesis 8: Suppose that M,D,andP are in a large interval and M[10,12],D[1.6,2.5],andP[2.15,3.25] . We can assume that c1=1.5,c2=0.5,c3=3.5,c4=12,c5=15,I=3,beta=0.1,J=0.2,andΦ=0.5 . Enterprises have a different probability of being honest, and supervisors have different probabilities for supervision, as x0=0.9,y0=0.1,andz0=0.9 . We used all the data to get the simulation Fig. 7.

images

Figure 7: Simulation of the dynamic strategy evolution of enterprises, informal institutions, and governments (4)

Under these assumptions, enterprises still faced high costs. Due to the supervision of the informal institutions and government regulation, enterprises faced high fines at the initial stage. Therefore, at the initial stage, enterprises had an increased probability of integrity cooperation. As time passed, enterprises found that the governments’ control decreased; enterprises could not obtain effective cost subsidies from the government. Even if they had to face the fines from informal institutions, the high cost they faced on their own may have been higher than the fine, so enterprises tended not to be honest during the knowledge sharing and cooperation in the later period. As the enterprises were dishonest in the cooperation-sharing, the informal institutions maintained a high level of supervision to improve benefits by fining the enterprises. If the informal institutions took their interests as the goal, they did not need to adjust their strategy. If the informal institutions wanted to promote the enterprises’ honesty in cooperation-sharing, increasing the punishment level is the best way.

Hypothesis 9: Based on the parameter assignment of Hypothesis 7, the initial strategy probability of the three parties in the game was adjusted, and we observed the dynamic strategy evolution of the three parties in the game. We assumed that x0=0.1,y0=0.9,andz0=0.1 , and the evolution chart of the tripartite dynamic strategy is shown in Fig. 8.

images

Figure 8: Simulation of the dynamic strategy evolution of enterprises, informal institutions, and governments (5)

As Fig. 8 shows, when the government and the informal institutions were unwilling to supervise and control in the early stage, the enterprises tended to be dishonest more quickly in cooperation-sharing. At the beginning of the game, the government and informal institutions showed their unwillingness to supervise, and the enterprises did not have the concern of high fines. Therefore, enterprises chose to be dishonest during the cooperation-sharing from the beginning. As the enterprises were dishonest, the government and informal institutions could increase their interest through fines. Therefore, both the informal institutions and the government chose to supervise and control the enterprises and then collect corresponding fines to increase benefits. Although the enterprises had a high probability of being honest during the cooperation, we observed that the government and informal institutions had a low probability of regulation and supervision. So, enterprises would tend not to be honest during the cooperation. As the level of dishonesty of the enterprises rose, both the government and the informal institutions hoped to restrain the occurrence of this phenomenon or seek profit for themselves in this way. Thus, the supervision probability of the informal institution quickly tended to be willing to supervise the enterprise. In the early stage, the government also hoped to be like the informal institutions to regulate effectively, but owing to the excessive level of subsidies, the government finally gave up the regulation.

5  Summary

Through analysis and research on the tripartite game among the government, enterprises, and informal institutions, we drew the following conclusions. The level of enterprises being honest in cooperation-sharing was affected by the external incentive, which refers to fines imposed by the government and informal institutions. Both the government and the informal institutions could encourage enterprises to be honest in cooperation-sharing. However, the government and informal institutions must consider more about the external incentive level. If the enterprises’ income from being dishonest in the cooperation-sharing is greater than the punishment, the enterprise continued to be dishonest in the cooperation-sharing while knowing that they would be punished. In such a situation, the external incentive mechanism was useless. If, however, the income level of dishonesty was lower than the punishment, enterprises preferred to be honest during the cooperation-sharing. The cost level of enterprises in the creative industry cluster had a decisive impact on whether they cooperated honestly.

The cost level also directly determined the level of the external incentive. The government and informal institutions should not make the external incentive level optional but decide after analyzing the enterprises’ income and cost level. A good credit market is conducive to the development of the industry and economy. However, if the government and the informal institutions still implement a higher level of external incentives to intervene in the case of higher enterprises’ cooperating costs, the enterprises may find themselves in a dilemma. Therefore, the enterprises’ cost level is at the core of the government and informal institutions when formulating a rational external incentive mechanism. Our study showed that the initial strategy state had no significant impact on the game. There was no great influence on the final steady states of the evolutionary game when the parameters were left unchanged, but they did adjust the initial probability of different strategies. No matter how much the initial state was, the game system approached the stable state when the cost and the external incentive level were in a relatively stable characteristic range. When the probability of government regulation was approaching zero, whether the enterprises chose to be honest during cooperation-sharing was more influenced by the informal institutions. The core influence was mainly related to the cooperating costs and the intensity of incentive and punishment from the informal institutions. Whether an enterprise chose to be honest during cooperation-sharing was also determined by the cooperating costs level and the relative level of external incentives. The external incentives had some impact on whether the enterprises were honest in cooperation-sharing. However, the enterprises’ cooperating cost level was the main factor affecting honesty in cooperation-sharing. Therefore, the rational external incentive should be based on the enterprise cost, and it should urge enterprises to be honest in cooperation-sharing. Ignoring the enterprises’ cost level and making the external incentive level optional could make cooperation-sharing more disorderly.

Funding Statement: General Program of National Natural Science Foundation of China (71874027).

Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest regarding the present study.

References

 1.  P. Su and Z. Li, “Matching mechanism of Chinese investment to domestic demand under the internal economic cycle,” On Economic Problems, no. 01, pp. 47–56, 2021. [Google Scholar]

 2.  C. Wu, V. Lee and M. E. McMurtrey, “Knowledge composition and its influence on new product development performance in the big data environment,” Computers, Materials & Continua, vol. 60, no. 1, pp. 365–378, 2019. [Google Scholar]

 3.  C. Wu, H. Yin, X. Yang, Z. Lu and M. E. McMurtrey, “Pricing method for big data knowledge based on a two-part tariff pricing scheme,” Intelligent Automation & Soft Computing, vol. 26, no. 5, pp. 1173–1184, 2020. [Google Scholar]

 4.  H. Zhou, T. Shen, X. L. Liu, Y. R. Zhang, P. Guo et al., “Knowledge graph: A survey of approaches and applications knowledge graph,” Journal on Artificial Intelligence, vol. 2, no. 2, pp. 89–101, 2020. [Google Scholar]

 5.  T. A. Hutton, “Reconstructed production landscapes in the postmodern city: Applied design and creative services in the metropolitan core,” Urban Geography, vol. 21, no. 4, pp. 285–317, 2013. [Google Scholar]

 6.  J. Howkins, The Creative Economy: How People Make Money from Ideas. London: The Penguin Press, 24–65, 2001. [Google Scholar]

 7.  J. Hartley, Creative Industries. U.S: Blackwell Publishing Ltd., 24–33, 2005. [Google Scholar]

 8.  J. Zhang, “A research on the impact of Multi-proximity of entrepreneurial firms on synergetic innovation relationship,” Science Research Management, vol. 39, no. 9, pp. 78–85, 2018. [Google Scholar]

 9.  Y. Wang and C. Yu, “Network structure and innovation knowledge flow in the cultural and creative industries cluster—based on the perspective of social network analysis,” Science and Technology, vol. 37, no. 11, pp. 158–163, 2017. [Google Scholar]

10. F. Wang and Y. Song, “Study on tacit knowledge sharing and shift in creativity industry clustering network,” Soft Science, vol. 27, no. 5, pp. 4–9, 2013. [Google Scholar]

11. Y. Jiang, Q. Liu, W. Dannah, D. Jin, X. Liu et al., “An optimized resource scheduling strategy for hadoop speculative execution based on non-cooperative game schemes,” Computers, Materials & Continua, vol. 62, no. 2, pp. 713–729, 2020. [Google Scholar]

12. C. Duan, J. Feng, H. Chang, J. Pan, L. Duan et al., “Research on sensor network coverage enhancement based on non-cooperative games,” Computers, Materials & Continua, vol. 60, no. 3, pp. 989–1002, 2019. [Google Scholar]

13. L. Wang and M. Pan, “Research on manufacturing enterprises knowledge sharing strategy of cooperative innovation,” Science& Technology Progress and Policy, vol. 37, no. 10, pp. 128–135, 2020. [Google Scholar]

14. A. Wu, Z. Wang and S. Chen, “Impact of specific investments, governance mechanisms and behaviors on the performance of cooperative innovation projects,” International Journal of Project Management, vol. 35, no. 3, pp. 504–515, 2017. [Google Scholar]

15. P. Ritala, H. Olander, S. Michaliloa and K. Husted, “Knowledge sharing, knowledge leaking and relative innovation performance: An empirical study,” Technovation, vol. 35, no. 3, pp. 22–31, 2015. [Google Scholar]

16. Z. Wu and L. Zhao, “Cooperative Innovation or Iindependent Iinnovation? ——an expanded AJ model and It's used in the internet industry of China,” Economic Management, vol. 33, no. 12, pp. 141–149, 2011. [Google Scholar]

17. Q. Zhou, W. Du and W. Han, “Technological standard alliance in China: Partner selection and innovation performance,” Journal of Science and Technology Policy in China, vol. 3, no. 3, pp. 196–209, 2012. [Google Scholar]

18. B. Yang, Y. Wang and X. Li, “The impact of multidimensional proximity on cooperative innovation,” Studies in Science of Science, vol. 1, pp. 154–164, 2019. [Google Scholar]

19. Y. Pan and S. Ni, “Opportunities and challenges of Sino——German science and technology innovation cooperation in the context of the Belt and Road Initiative,” Scientific Management Research, vol. 3, no. 6, pp. 116–119, 2018. [Google Scholar]

20. J. Wu, X. X. Peng, Y. X. Sheng, L. Peng, Q. F. Shi et al., “Research on knowledge transfer cooperative Game in university-Industry cooperation based on dynamic control model,” Chinese Journal of Management Science, vol. 25, no. 30, pp. 190–196, 2018. [Google Scholar]

21. S. Shang and Z. Zhang, “The knowledge sharing of virtual enterprise based on evolutionary game,” China Soft Science, vol. 93, pp. 150–157, 2015. [Google Scholar]

22. K. Tan, P. Wong and L. Chung, “Information and knowledge leakage in supply chain,” Information Systems Frontiers, vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 621–638, 2016. [Google Scholar]

23. J. Xu, J. Fu and F. Li, “Research on the service innovation diffusion of manufacturing enterprises based on evolutionary game theory,” Operation Research and Management Science, vol. 27, no. 7, pp. 177–183, 2018. [Google Scholar]

24. M. Gürtler and O. Gürtler, “The interaction of explicit and implicit contracts: A signaling approach,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, vol. 9, no. 6, pp. 108–146, 2014. [Google Scholar]

images This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.