iconOpen Access

ARTICLE

crossmark

Optimal Strategies Trajectory with Multi-Local-Worlds Graph

by Xiang Yu1, Chonghua Wang2, Xiaojing Zheng3,*, Chaoyu Zeng4, Brij B. Gupta5,6,7

1 School of Electronics and Information Engineering, Taizhou University, Taizhou, Zhejiang, 318000, China
2 China Industrial Control Systems Cyber Emergency Response Team, Beijing, 100040, China
3 School of Economics and Management, Weifang University of Science and Technology, Shouguang, Shandong, 262700, China
4 National Computer System Engineering Research Institute of China, Beijing, 102699, China
5 Department of Computer Science and Information Engineering, Asia University, Taiwan, Taichung, 413, China
6 Research and Innovation Department, Skyline University College, Sharjah, P.O. Box 1797, United Arab Emirates
7 Staffordshire University, Stoke-on-Trent, ST4 2DE, UK

* Corresponding Author: Xiaojing Zheng. Email: email

Computers, Materials & Continua 2023, 75(1), 2079-2099. https://doi.org/10.32604/cmc.2023.034118

Abstract

This paper constructs a non-cooperative/cooperative stochastic differential game model to prove that the optimal strategies trajectory of agents in a system with a topological configuration of a Multi-Local-World graph would converge into a certain attractor if the system’s configuration is fixed. Due to the economics and management property, almost all systems are divided into several independent Local-Worlds, and the interaction between agents in the system is more complex. The interaction between agents in the same Local-World is defined as a stochastic differential cooperative game; conversely, the interaction between agents in different Local-Worlds is defined as a stochastic differential non-cooperative game. We construct a non-cooperative/cooperative stochastic differential game model to describe the interaction between agents. The solutions of the cooperative and non-cooperative games are obtained by invoking corresponding theories, and then a nonlinear operator is constructed to couple these two solutions together. At last, the optimal strategies trajectory of agents in the system is proven to converge into a certain attractor, which means that strategies trajectory are certainty as time tends to infinity or a large positive integer. It is concluded that the optimal strategy trajectory with a nonlinear operator of cooperative/non-cooperative stochastic differential game between agents can make agents in a certain Local-World coordinate and make the Local-World payment maximize, and can make the all Local-Worlds equilibrated; furthermore, the optimal strategy of the coupled game can converge into a particular attractor that decides the optimal property.

Keywords


1  Introduction

In the last 20 years, the theoretic study of complex adaptive systems has become a significant field. A broad range of complex adaptive systems has been studied, from abstract ones, such as the evolution of the economic system and the criticality of the complex adaptive system, to physical systems, such as city traffic designing and management decisions. These all have in common the property one cannot hope to explain their detailed structures, properties, and functions exactly from a mathematical viewpoint. By the 2010s, there were rich theories of stochastic differential games describing agent’s behavior of interacting coupled with the optimal strategies in a transitory deterministic structure, and there have been many random complex networks models describe the evolutionary law under specific logical rules in various fields, which makes complex adaptive system studying colorfully. These two problems are essential due to this management complex adaptive system.

On the one hand, Hachijo et al. [1] studied the agent’s interaction with others according to a Boolean game in random complex networks. Lera et al. [2] and Li et al. [3], on the other hand, reported that the agent interact with others according to certain games, such as a stochastic differential game, which has been studied by Javarone [4], Mcavoy et al. [5], Gächter et al. [6]. However, few scientific research results indicate that if these two problems are combined, the existing research cannot support the making-decision process in reality.

Suppose that the system configuration is a fixed graph; the interaction between agents happens in a certain Multi-Local-World graph. Invoke Hypothesis 1–2 specified in the following Section, the interaction between agents can be thought of as two categories: a cooperative game between homogenous agents in the same Local-World and a non-cooperative game between in-homogenous agents in different Local-Worlds. According to the theory of emergence, an exclusive phenomenon of the complex adaptive system of the non-cooperative game between agents in different Local-Worlds can be coarsened in size to the non-cooperative game Γ(s,x,u) coupled with the corresponding payoff V(s,x,u) between Super-Agents, which has been studied by Calvert et al. [7] and Gächter et al. [6]. However, the behaviors between agents in the same Local-World can be described as the cooperative stochastic differential game Γc(s,x,u), which can be separated into two sequential problems: the first one is to simplify it as a corresponding optimal problem ϖ, and the second one is to distribute the maximum payoff rationally among all agents in the system; furthermore, the corresponding optimal payoff for this Super-agent is denoted to ϖi(s,xi,u), which has been studied by Friesz et al. [8], Querini et al. [9], then, a payoff distribution procedure could be designed to distribute payoff rationally between Agents.

The most important thing to this problem should be not only the existence of a solution to the optimal strategy but also the property of the optimal strategy and the stability of the solution. However, several questions perplex us: all agents in this system are always partially intelligent, partially autonomous, and partial society. They interact with others according to the interactive rules of both cooperative and non-cooperative games. So, getting the corresponding optimal strategies is the most important and difficult thing due to these two mixed interactions. According to theories of operational research and game theory, for an arbitrary Super-Agent, the payoff coupled with a non-cooperative game with other Super-Agents always is not identical to the payoff coupled with the optimal problem that is the first process of the cooperative game to other Agents, even if the same strategy is considered. So, how to make up for this difference must be our purpose. As well known, whether the imputation mechanism designed is rational or not decides whether the solution is stable or not. To resolve this problem, an adjusted dynamical Shapley is constructed; whether the adjusted dynamical Shapley vector can make the solution stable or not is what we focus on if non-cooperative/cooperative games are considered together.

As far as this complex adaptive system coupled with those gaps introduced above is considered, a non-cooperative/cooperative stochastic differential game model for the agent’s dynamical, intelligent and social properties has been constructed. The corresponding solutions respective to these two models are obtained by invoking classic analytic methods and processes. At last, a nonlinear operator is constructed to pair the Nash strategies with Pareto strategies together so that each agent in the system can select its optimal strategies under certain conditions. Because of optimal dynamic optimal strategies, this complex adaptive system synchronizes locally but not globally, making this system more stable to operate and more innovative to fit for change. To ensure that the optimal strategies are stable and can converge into a certain attractor, an adjusted Shapley vector is introduced in the payoff distribution procedure to make all agents more rational and dynamically stable over a long period. The details of the model are specified in the next section. This paper considers a coexisting game of the stochastic differential cooperative game and stochastic differential non-cooperative game, which is more close to reality; furthermore, we design a rational payment distribution mechanism driven by an adjusted dynamical Shapley value, which is proven to be much more stable under certain conditions. These two innovations make this paper more interesting.

2  The Model

Following a complex adaptive system for Agent behavior and local topological configuration co-evolving, let’s consider.

Definition 1. S=(𝒢,𝒜,π)(Ω,,P,(Xtβ)tT0) is called the stochastic differential game model with a random Multi-Local-Worlds graph. If

(1)   Topological space 𝒢 describes the interactive configuration of the system, which is the set of graphs C=(C1,C2,,Cp), Ci=(Ci1,Ci2,,Ciri(t)) 1ip is called Super-Agent, Ci is the first order segmentation of the system, and Cij,1jri(t), which is called agent, is the second order segmentation of the system. 𝒜 is strategies space, which describes all possible behaviors of agents in this system and π is the payoff.

(2)   Xβ=(Xtβ)tT0 is a family of Ω-valued random variables indexed by discrete time parameters t and a noise parameter β. is a σ algebra, and ℙ a probability measure.

(3)   A realization {Xtβ=𝒢} defines an action α in the graph C.

(4)   The interaction law of agents can be proposed based on following hypotheses:

Hypothesis 1. Several different Local-Worlds are large enough such that there are sufficient agents interact with the others within this Local-World, and who are small enough such that there exist sufficient Local-Worlds interact with others in this system.

Hypothesis 2. In a short time scale, each agent interacts with the others who are in the same Local World can be defined as a cooperative game, i.e., all agents pursue the maximized profit of the Local-World first, then distribute the system profit rationally. Each Local World interacts with the others according to the rule of a non-cooperative game such that the system is equilibrated. On a long time scale, the behaviors and configuration of the system can be converted into a certain attractor.

Due to this paper’s limited space and the process’s complexity, just 2-levels of the system are analyzed as an example. If the system’s levels are larger than or equal to 3, the results can be linearly extended directly. According to the property defined in Hypothesis 1 and 2, the system configuration can be described as Fig. 1.

images

Figure 1: Interaction between agents in the dynamic topology of the complex adaptive system

Fig. 1 describes the dynamic property of the complex adaptive system with co-evolving behavior and local configuration. Where C represents “Cooperation games” happen in agents and N represents “Non-cooperation games” happen in agents. There are two local-worlds in this system. Suppose that an arbitrary agent should not pursue maximizing the current payoff. However, the payoff is maximized in a specific time scale, which means that an agent can give up the transitory benefit but the total payoff in the corresponding time scale—they think the payment is decided by a certain integral of the transitory objectivity function at a continuous time. Furthermore, the agent’s behavior is limited by the corresponding resource that is described as a stochastic dynamics equation such that agents’ objectivity will be changed synchronized, which should be described by a certain discount function ϕ(t) at the time. This paper uses three discount functions, homogenous exponential distribution describing the agent’s uniform and stable behavior on every time scale. Inhomogeneous exponential distribution =t0Th=1mexp[t0srh(y)dy]ds describing the agent’s non-uniform behavior on small sequential time scales, and Lévy distribution =t0Tp2πr3exp[p24r]ds, which describes the agent who can imitate others’ behavior and interact directly, are introduced to describe the diversity of behaviors. In the interaction process, agents make decisions relying on themselves, neighbors’ states, and the properties of the environment. Agents in the system are intelligent and social as Eqs. (1)(8), making this system a complex adaptive system.

Firstly, some symbols and variables appeared in this paper should be listed in Table 1.

images

Suppose that there are m Local-Worlds in the system, denoted by Super-Agent i, and the jth player of Super-Agent i is denoted by an agent ji. Then the system configuration mentioned above can be described as the corresponding adjacency matrix G=(G1,G2,,Gm). Except for the system topology, interaction property should also be mastered if one needs to identify this system. Furthermore, the complex interactive mix between cooperative and non-cooperative games makes the system more complex. This paper aims to obtain the optimal strategies trajectory for this complex interaction.

As well known, the property of a complex adaptive system of economy and management is random time-varying. In this paper, according to the economic and management system’s property, three different systems with the statistical property of agents’ behaviors, homogeneous exponent distribution, inhomogeneous exponent distribution, and Lévy distribution, are studied respectively, which should be shown as follow.

To analyze this problem effectively, we consider the Super-Agent’s behavior. For arbitrary Super-Agent, its state dynamics are characterized by the set of vector-valued differential equations

dxi(s)=fi[s,xi(s),xj(s),ui(s)]ds+σi[s,xi(s)]dzi(s),xi(t0)=xi0,jiN(1)

And the corresponding objectivities are

Et0{t0Tgj[s,xj(s),uj(s)]exp[t0sr(y)dy]ds+exp[t0Tr(y)dy]qj(xj(T))}(2)

Et0{t0Tgj[s,xj(s),uj(s)]h=1m{whexp[t0srh(y)dy]}ds+h=1m[whexp[t0Trh(y)dy]qj(xj(T))]}(3)

where, jM={1,2,,m}, and

Et0{t0Tgj[s,xj(s),uj(s)][t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]ds+[t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]qj(xj(T))}(4)

describe three behaviors driven by the discount functions with homogeneous exponential distribution, inhomogeneous exponent distribution, and Lévy distribution, respectively.

Similarly, as for an arbitrary agent ji whose behavior statistical character satisfies homogeneous exponent distribution, the state dynamics is characterized by the set of vector-valued differential equation

Et0{t0Tgji[s,xji(s),uji(s)]exp[t0sr(y)dy]ds+exp[t0Tr(y)dy]qji(xji(T))}

where, xi(s)XiRmi denotes the system statute of the agent i, ujiUicompRi is the control vector of the agent i, exp[t0sr(y)dy] is the discount factor, qi(xi(T)) is the terminal payoff. In particular, gi[s,xi(s),ui(s)] and qi(x) are all positively related to xi. σi[s,xi(s)] is a mji×Θi and zi(s) is a Θ-dimensional Wiener process with an initial state xi0. Let Ωi[s,xi(s)]=σi[s,xi]σi[s,xi]T denote the covariance matrix of h rows and ζ columns. For ij,xixj=ϕ, zi(s) and zj are independent Wiener processes.

The set of vector-valued differential equations characterizes the state dynamics of Agent ji.

dxji(s)=fji[s,xji(s),uji(s)]ds+σjidz,xji(t0)=xji0,forji{1,2,,iri}Ni(5)

Similarly, the state dynamics for inhomogeneous exponent distribution and Lévy distribution of agent ji is the same as Eq. (5), and their objectivity can be expressed to

Et0{t0Tgji[s,xji(s),uji(s)]h=1m{whexp[t0srh(y)dy]}ds+exp[t0Tr(y)dy]qji(xji(T))},jM={1,2,,m}

Et0{t0Tgji[s,xji(s),uji(s)][t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]ds+[t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]qji(xji(T))}

respectively. To simplify this problem, we consider the cooperative game between arbitrary Agents ji in an arbitrary Super-Agent i, then study the different non-cooperative games between the Super-Agent for the cooperative game. The most important for cooperation between these agents is the objectivity of the Super-Agent’s payoff, so,

Et0{t0TjiKigji[s,xji(s),uji(s)]exp[t0sr(y)dy]ds+jiKiexp[t0Tr(y)dy]qji(xji(T))},jiKi={1,2,,ki}Ni(6)

Et0{t0TjiKigji[s,xji(s),uji(s)]h=1m{whexp[t0srh(y)dy]}ds+jiKih=1m{whexp[t0Trh(y)dy]}qji(xji(T))},jiKi={1,2,,ki}Ni(7)

Et0{t0TjiKigji[s,xji(s),uji(s)][t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]ds+jiKi[t0Tp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]qji(xji(T))},jiKi={1,2,,ki}Ni(8)

Historical strategies and local topological configuration determine agents’ payoffs. When an agent ji interacts with others and the environment, other agents’ behaviors should be deterministic such that the behaviors in the Local-World are coordinated if the system is in equilibrium. However, this kind of coordination will be shifted when the system’s topological configuration changes from one deterministic one to another. So, the interaction between the agents is full of dynamic, random, nonlinear, and diverse.

Invoke the models mentioned above, and it is easy to know: it is not only the payoff maximized should be considered, but also the optimal payoff should be maintained stably in a much longer time scale, which means that agents must give up the short-period objectivity to pursue to the long-period objectivity once these two different objects conflict. Furthermore, the optimal strategy would change as the environment changing, which the random dynamics and objectivity can reflect. It is easy to know that each agent would adapt to his current and historical state, the stats of other agents that interact with him, and the environment by using different strategies; when an agent makes a decision, he does consider not only the current state of the system but also the historic states coupling with the evolutionary property, which is important. An arbitrary agent in this complex adaptive system is intelligent because an arbitrary agent in this complex system can make a decision and update strategy relying on its historical states and other agents’ strategies that interact directly. When an agent decides, it must forecast the future state to keep the strategies from making mistakes. The future state can be obtained from the corresponding trend term of the state equation constrained. However, because of the floating term in the behavior dynamics equation, the future state cannot be forecasted precisely. So, the strategies of an arbitrary agent should be set to an adaptable interval to make up the wrong or incorrect decision, which makes the agent autonomous.

3  Main Results

3.1 Agent’s Payoff

According to (1) and (2), an arbitrary super-agent interacts with others, which is a non-cooperative game. Similar, arbitrary agents interact with others in the same Local-World according to (4) and (5). The interaction is defined as a cooperative game. Considering the complexity, following analytic method should be invoked, as specified in Table 2.

images

There are two theorems would be given. When the system achieves equilibrium, the transitory payoff for an arbitrary agent in this complex adaptive system can be described as:

Theorem 1. For allxNitXNit,

(1)   The payoff of agentji for systems (1), (2), (5) and (6) is

v(t0)ji(t,xNit)=KiNi|𝒩¯ji(ki1)!(niki)!ni!×[exp[r(st0)]W(t0)Ki(t,xKit)qexp[r(st0)]W(t0)Kiji(t,xKijit)q]

(2)   The payoff of agentji for systems (1), (3), (6) and (7) is

v(t0)ji(t,xNit)=KiNi|𝒩¯ji(ki1)!(niki)!ni!×[h=1{whexp[rh(st0)]}W(t0)Ki(t,xKit)qh=1{whexp[rh(st0)]}W(t0)Kiji(t,xKijit)q]

(3)   The payoff of agent ji for systems (1), (4), (6) and (8) is

v(t0)ji(t,xNit)=KiNi|𝒩¯ji(ki1)!(niki)!ni![1πrexp[14r(τ2t02)]W(t0)Ki(t,xKit)q×1πrexp[14r(τ2t02)]W(t0)Kiji(t,xKijit)q]

where, W denotes the optimal of the coalitionKi, q=||(gxxt)/(fxxt)|| is a constant smaller than or equal to 1.

However, it is clear from Theorem 1 that the optimal payoff of the agent ji depends on the transitory time t, not the arbitrary time τ[t0,T]. Furthermore, the arbitrary agent ji cannot obtain the global information of time τ at that time, so there are some gaps in the optimal decision. For compensating this fault, the transitory compensatory mechanism should be introduced.

3.2 Transitory Compensatory of Arbitrary Agent

Theorem 2. On timeτ[t0,T]

(1)   The transitory compensatory agentjiNi of the system (1), (2), (5) and (6) should be described as

ji(τ)=exp[r(st0)]KiNi|𝒩¯ji(ki1)!(niki)!ni!×{[Wt(τ)Ki(t,xKiτ)|t=τ]q[Wt(τ)Kiji(t,xKijiτ)|t=τ]q+{[WxNτ(τ)Ki(t,xKiτ)|t=τ]q[WxNτ(τ)Kiji(t,xKijiτ)|t=τ]q}fNi[τ,xNiτ,ψji(τ)Ni(τ,xNiτ)]+12hp^ζp=1niΩKihp^ζp(τ,xτ)[Wxthp^xtζp(τ)Ki(t,xt)|t=τ]q12hp^ζp=1niΩKijihp^ζp(τ,xτ)[Wxthp^xtζp(τ)Kiji(t,xt)|t=τ]q}

(2)   The transitory compensatory agentjiNi of the system (1), (3), (6) and (7) should be described as

ji(τ)=h=1H{whexp[rh(st0)]}KiNi|𝒩¯ji(ki1)!(niki)!ni!×{[Wt(τ)Ki(t,xKiτ)|t=τ]q[Wt(τ)Kiji(t,xKijiτ)|t=τ]q+{[WxNτ(τ)Ki(t,xKiτ)|t=τ]q[WxNτ(τ)Kiji(t,xKijiτ)|t=τ]q}fNi[τ,xNiτ,ψji(τ)Ni(τ,xNiτ)]+12hp^ζp=1niΩKihp^ζp(τ,xτ)[Wxthp^xtζp(τ)Ki(t,xt)|t=τ]q12hp^ζp=1niΩKijihp^ζp(τ,xτ)[Wxthp^xtζp(τ)Kiji(t,xt)|t=τ]q}

(3)   The transitory compensatory agentjiNi of the system (1), (4), (6) and (8) should be described as

ji(τ)=1πrexp[14r(τ2t02)]KiNi|𝒩¯ji(ki1)!(niki)!ni!×{[Wt(τ)Ki(t,xKiτ)|t=τ]q[Wt(τ)Kiji(t,xKijiτ)|t=τ]q+{[WxNτ(τ)Ki(t,xKiτ)|t=τ]q[WxNτ(τ)Kiji(t,xKijiτ)|t=τ]q}fNi[τ,xNiτ,ψji(τ)Ni(τ,xNiτ)]+12hp^ζp=1niΩKihp^ζp(τ,xτ)[Wxthp^xtζp(τ)Ki(t,xt)|t=τ]q12hp^ζp=1niΩKijihp^ζp(τ,xτ)[Wxthp^xtζp(τ)Kiji(t,xt)|t=τ]q}

where,xNi(τ)=xNiτXNiτ make Condition 1 implement.ji(τ) is the transitory compensatory of Agent ji at transitory time τ for distributing payoff fairly, which can lead to the dynamical stable solution of the coalition. Wt(τ)Ki is the payoff of coalition Ki at time τ under cooperative game Γ, n is population of agents in system.

4  Behavior and the Equilibrium of the Agent in Multi-Local-Worlds Graph

4.1 The Cooperative Stochastic Differential Game Between Agents of Super-Agent

Regarding the cooperative stochastic differential game, two problems why an arbitrary agent will cooperate with others and how much it will get coupled with a certain optimal strategy must be considered. In this sense, the conflicts between coalition and individual rationality should be considered. Scientists insist that the essence of a cooperative stochastic differential game is to distribute the payoff between agents in the system after its profit is maximized. As mentioned above, two problems must be considered. The first is optimizing this system by invoking Bellman dynamic programming theorem, Pontryagain’s stochastic optimization theorem, and Fleming theorem, then transferring the optimal problem to a corresponding Hamilton-Jacobi-Isaacs equation, which has been resolved respectively by Chighoub et al. [10], Guo et al. [11], Gomoyunov [12]. The second one is constructing a payoff distribution procedure for all agents [13,14]. These papers discuss the properties and relationships among the kernel, the nucleolus, and the minimum core of the cooperative game. It is concluded that the Shapley value is a relatively feasible method for distributing the payoff among the agents in the system if coalition rationality constraint conditions and individual rationality constraint conditions are considered.

However, these conclusions lack analyzing of time-varied of the system, which makes the results far from reality. Furthermore, human behavior is very uncertain and cannot be recognized and take on the property of diversity, which means that every agent has different behaviors at a time, and he can select a strategy randomly, which makes the deterministic conclusions mentioned cannot fit for the real complex system and must be adjusted to satisfy this requirement. In this paper, we omit the diversity of the behavior and abstract them to a certain effort level. It means every agent’s behavior transfers the input to output by laboring and maximizing the output for a long time. In this sense, simplifying human behaviors is the most important thing one must study. This paper will analyze the system’s property according to this idea.

4.1.1 Payoff Maximized of the Sub-System

Because the first process is to optimize an arbitrary Local-World i, i.e., Super-Agent i and the corresponding optimal strategies can be expressed to a PDE, which has the following formation:

Vt(t,x)12h,ζ=1Ωhζ(t,x)Vxhxζ(t,x)=maxu{g[t,x,u]exp[t0tr(y)dy]+Vx(t,x)f[t,x,u]}

and V(T,x)=q(x)exp[t0Tr(y)dy]+Vx(t,x)f[t,x,u]

As far as the agent’s behavior of discount function with homogeneous exponential distribution is considered, this is the basic representation. If agent’s behavior satisfies the distribution function of in-homogenous exponential distribution and Lévy distribution, a similar representation will be copied except for the discount functions. So, it is concluded that the strategies are independent of the agent’s property if all agents have identical properties, i.e., all agents have the same distribution but have different parameters of the dynamics function. This result should be seen in Lemma 1 and the corresponding proof in Supplementary Material. Furthermore, the corresponding optimal strategies trajectory should be specified by Theorem 3 coupled with corresponding proofs in Supplementary Material for the discount function of the homogenous exponential distribution, Theorem 4, and Lemma 2, Lemma 3, Corollary 1 and Corollary 2 coupled with corresponding proofs in Supplementary Material for the discount function of the in-homogenous exponential distribution, and Corollary 3, Corollary 4 and Corollary 4 coupled with corresponding proofs in Supplementary Material for the discount function of Lévy distribution.

4.1.2 Dynamical Shapley Value for Distribution Coalition’s Payoff

Firstly, some necessary conditions should be introduced in this paper. As well known, an agent feels rational if the following conditions are all satisfied: (1) The sum of all agent’s payoff distributed must equal to the maximum payoff of this Local-World; (2) As far as each agent in this system is considered, the payoff distributed that he take part in the cooperation must be not less than the one that he does not take part in the cooperation. The former is called coalition rationality, and the latter is called an individual coalition. Many scientists provide a rational imputation payoff method, for example, Shapley value, to distribute payoff rationally between Agents in Super-Agent. It is proven right that dynamical Shapley has the property of joint stability and sub-game consistency [15]. In this sense, the agent’s payoff in arbitrary Local-World would be calculated, and so would the corresponding optimal strategies.

Condition 1: System rational constraint Dynamical Shapley value imputation vector

v(τ)ji(τ,xNiτ)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni![W(τ)Ki(τ,xKiτ)W(τ)Kiji(τ,xKijiτ)]

jiNi,τ[t0,T] and xNiτXNiτ, where

v(τ)i(τ,xNiτ)=[v(τ)1(τ,xNiτ),v(τ)2(τ,xNiτ),,v(τ)ni(τ,xNiτ)]

Satisfying,

(1)   ji=1niv(τ)ji(τ,xNiτ)=W(τ)Ni(τ,xNiτ)

(2)   v(τ)ji(τ,xNiτ)W(τ)ji(τ,xNjτ) for all jiNi and τ[t0,T]

where, (1) of Condition 1 guarantee v(τ)(τ,xNiτ) satisfies Pareto optimization and coalition rational, and (2) v(τ)(τ,xNiτ) makes the individual rationality satisfied, i.e., each agent’s payoff after cooperating is not less than the one before cooperating. Furthermore, an arbitrary Agent in this complex adaptive system may play with all other Agents, producing several deterministic coalitions that map the cooperative states. Set ji(s) is the transitory payoff distributed of the agent ji at the time s[t0,T] coupled with v(t0)ji(t0,xNi0), see Condition 2.

Condition 2:

ji=1niij(s)=ji=1nigji[s,xjis,ψNi(t0)Ni(s,xjis)], for t[τ,T] and xNitXNit

From these two conditions, it is easy to see that an arbitrary Agent feels rational if and only if the deviation among all possible payoffs is the least minimum.

It is concluded that the Shapley vector satisfies Condition 1 and Condition 2. According to the dynamical Shapley value and cooperative game theory, we can know the agent will take the strategy vector of {ψNi(t0)Ni(t,xNit)}t=t0T in whole time intervals [t0,T], with the optimal state trajectory {xNi(t)}t=t0T. Set the initial state is xNi0 at the time t0 the payoff distributed to the agent ji under coordination should be

v(t0)ji(t0,xNi0)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni![Wt0Ki(t0,xKi0)Wt0Kiji(t0,xKiji0)],jiNi

This kind of distribution fits the initial state but unfits for arbitrary time. The state is always changed dynamically, which makes the optimal strategies change randomly, too. Here, a dynamical imputation mechanism must be constructed to fit the real complex management system, i.e.,

v(t0)ji(t,xNit)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni![W(t0)Ki(t,xKit)W(t0)Kiji(t,xKijit)]

where xNitXNit.

The fairness of the concept is provided using the Theorem below.

Theorem 3. The transitory payoff distributed to the agent jiNi at a time τ[t0,T] equal to:

ji(τ)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni!{[Wt(τ)Ki(t,xKiτ)|t=τ][Wt(τ)Kii(t,xKiτ)|t=τ]+([WxNiτ(τ)Ki(t,xKiτ)|t=τ][WxNiτ(τ)Kiji(t,xKijiτ)|t=τ])fNi[τ,xNiτ,ψji(τ)Ni(τ,xNiτ)]+12hi,ζi=1niΩKihiζi(τ,xτ)[Wxthi(τ)Kt(t,xt)|t=τ]12hi,ζi=1niΩKiihiζi(τ,xτ)[Wxthixt(τ)Kiici(t,xt)|t=τ]}

wherexNi(τ)=xNiτXNiτ will make Condition 1 be implemented.

The proof is finished by invoking Lemma 2 and Theorem 6 in Supplementary Material. The specification meaning should be seen in Remark 1 and Remark 2 in Supplementary Material. An example is given to specify this process in Zheng et al. [16], to explain the agent’s coordination strategy and effort level in the stochastic cooperative differential game framework. In fact, the rational payoff distributed and the corresponding compensatory is independent of the discount function; the distinction is in detail in the imputation process.

4.2 The Noncooperative Stochastic Differential Game Between Super-Agents

An Arbitrary Local-World is regarded as a Super-Agent, in this case, suppose that there are m Super-Agents in this system. According to Hypothesis 1–2, we can know, the interaction between these Super-Agents is a non-cooperative stochastic differential game Γ. So, the corresponding model is constructed as follows.

For an arbitrary Super-Agent i, its objective should be described as

Et0{t0Tgi[s,xi(s),ui(s)]exp[t0sr(y)dy]ds+exp[t0Tr(y)dy]qi(xi(T))},iM(9)

The corresponding constraint equation should be:

dxi(s)=fi[s,xi(s),ui(s)]ds+σi[s,xi(s)]dzi(s),xi(t0)=xi0(10)

There must exist a Nash equilibrium point for the system. Due to its complexity in resolving the optimal problem, another PDE is introduced to give the corresponding solution identical to the optimal strategy of the non-cooperative stochastic differential game.

Lemma 1. A set of controlsu(t)=ϕ(t,x) constitutes an optimal solution to the problems introduced above, if there exists a continuously differentiable functionV(t,x):[t0,T]×RmR satisfying the following partial differential equation

Vt(t,x)12h,ζ=1Ωhζ(t,x)Vxhxζ(t,x)=maxu{g[t,x,u]exp[t0tr(y)dy]+Vx(t,x)f[t,x,u]}

andV(T,x)=q(x)exp[t0Tr(y)dy]+Vx(t,x)f[t,x,u].

As far as other discount functions are considered, similar forms are reflected except for the discount function. The corresponding proof should invoke Lemma 3 and Corollary 3 in Supplementary Material.

4.3 Coupling Between the Noncooperative Game of Super-Agent and the Cooperative Game of Agent

So far, the optimal strategy coupled with a cooperative stochastic differential game between agents in a certain Local-World and the Nash optimal strategy coupled with a non-cooperative stochastic differential game between differential Local-Worlds has been obtained. However, there exists another paradox: the optimal strategy due to the cooperative stochastic differential game between Agents in a certain Super-Agent is not identical to the optimal strategy of the agent. This is because of complex interaction mixed as a Non-cooperative game and cooperative game, which means the most important research for obtaining the optimal strategy of the system is to find an algorithm to couple these two different optimal strategies together. According to Proposition 1, shown in Supplementary Material, it is evident that the optimal solution for the Cooperative game in Super-Agent is feasible. Let’s reconsider the essence of these two kinds of games. As far as the cooperative stochastic differential game between Agents in this Local-World is considered, the corresponding optimal strategy of arbitrary agents comes from a rationally distributed payoff. In fact, the total payoff comes from the non-cooperative stochastic differential game between Super-Agents.

So, it is the identical relationship between optimization and game theory shows that there is a mapping between the Nash optimal solution V(s,x,u) of a non-cooperative stochastic differential game Γ(s,x,u) and the optimal solution W(s,x,u) of an optimization problem ϖ(s,x,u). Invoke the definition of the optimal solution and introduce the proof process of Theorem 2.5.1 of Yeung et al. [17], it is easy to say that The Nash optimal solution of Super-Agent is one feasible solution of the optimal problem, so there must be a nonlinear operator between them, which will be obtained as follows.

According to the theory of calculus of variations, a nonlinear operator ϑ(s,x,u) is constructed in this paper such that there is a strong relationship between these two optimal solutions mentioned above, i.e., V(s,x,u)=ϑ(s,x,u)W(s,x,u)+o((s,x,u)), where ϑ(s,x,u)=φ(s,x,u,V(s,x,u))/W(s,x,u). Combining these two different optimal strategies, we know that the following Theorem should be invoked as far as the discount functions with different homogenous exponential distributions are considered.

Theorem 4. There must be a functionφ(x) such thatV(s,x,u)=φ(W(s,x,u))

(1)   As for the complex system of management with a discount function of the homogenous exponential distribution, we have

1)   φ(t,x)=exp[r(tt0)]x if the gameΓ is an infinite-horizon feedback game;

2)   φ(t,x)=o(exp[r(tt0)]xq), and0<q<1 if the gameΓ is a feedback game.

(2)   As for the complex system of management with the discount function of the in-homogenous exponential distribution, we have

1)   φ(t,x)=h=1{whexp[rh(tt0)]}x if the gameΓ is an infinite-horizon feedback game;

2)   φ(t,x)=o(h=1{whexp[rh(tt0)]}xq), and0<q<1 if the gameΓ is a feedback game.

(3)   As for the complex system of management with the discount function with Lévy distribution, we have

1)   φ(t,x)=1πrexp[14r(τ2t02)]x if the gameΓ is an infinite-horizon feedback game;

2)   φ(t,x)=o(1πrexp[14r(τ2t02)]xq), and0<q<1 if the gameΓ is a feedback game.

Theorem 4 couples the cooperative stochastic differential game between agents in an arbitrary Local-World and the non-cooperative stochastic differential game between Super-Agents. By invoking this result, the agent’s optimal strategy in the system must be obtained. The proof of Theorem 4 should invoke Proposition 1, Theorem 1, Theorem 5, and Theorem 6 in Supplementary Material.

5  The Stability of Agents’ Behaviour in Deterministic Multi-Local-World Graph

Section 4 shows us the Agent’s Nash-Pareto optimal solution of the complex system of management coupled with the game theory model in a Multi-Local-World graph. Scientists think the solution is stable if the optimal solution of a cooperative stochastic differential game is stable, which means the synchronism, coordination, and stability are all satisfied, which will be analyzed in this Section. However, stability must be discussed to promise the scientific character of the solution.

The stability of the cooperative stochastic differential game solution decides whether optimal equilibrium strategies are feasible or not. Intuitively, the stability of the solution of the corresponding Hamilton-Jacobi-Isaacs equation and the stability of the Shapley decide the stability of the optimal strategies. However, scientists have not yet discussed the attractor of these optimal strategies’ trajectory.

Definition 2. The following vector is the adjusted Shapley vector if

Sh~ji(x0)=k=0m1sksk+1Shjik+1(x~(s))ji=1nigji(sk,x~(s))V(x~(s),Ts;Ni)(11)

As for the sub-game v(x~(s),Ts),s[sl,sl+1),l=0,1,2,,m1], the adjusted Shapley vector is defined according to

Sh~ji(x0)=ssk+1Shjik+1(x~(s))ji=1nigji(sl,x~(s))V(x~(s),Ts;Ni)+k=l+1m1sksk+1Shjik+1(x~(s))ji=1nigji(sk,x~(s))V(x~(s),Ts;Ni)(12)

Introduce the adjusted Shapley vector compensatory program, γ(s) which is defined as

γji(s)=Shjik+1(x~(s))ji=1nigji(sk,x~(s))V(x~(s),Ts;Ni),s[sl,sl+1)(13)

Obviously, γji(s)0.

So, Sh~ji(x0) satisfies the properties of inter-coordinative, realizable and super-addition, which should be considered in the complex system.

The Nash-Pareto optimal solution of the cooperative stochastic differential game with the discount function of the homogenous exponential distribution is stable if the corresponding Shapley imputation and the corresponding compensatory mentioned in Theorem 4 and Theorem 5 in Supplementary Material are proven to be adjusted Shapley vectors, respectively. The detailed proof can be seen in Lemma 4 and Lemma 5, coupled with the proof in Supplementary Material. In this sense, the point of this problem is transferred to find the strong condition of this mapping.

We know that the dynamical distribution mechanism for payoff and the compensatory mechanism described describe the properties of three complex management systems, driven by agent behavior coupled with the homogeneous discount function of the exponential distribution exp[r(st0)], an inhomogeneous discount function of the exponential distribution h=1{whexp[rh(st0)]} and Lévy distribution 1πrexp[14r(s2t02)], respectively.

As for the first case, the payoff imputation is

v(t0)ij(t0,xNi0)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni![W(t0)K(t0,xKit0)W(t0)Kiji(t0,xKiji0)]=Et0{t0Tji(s)exp[t0sr(y)dy]ds+qji(xji(T))exp[t0Tr(y)dy]xNi(t0)=xNi0}=Et0{t0Tji(s)exp[r(st0)]ds+qji(xji(T))exp[r(Tt0)]xNi(t0)=xNi0}

and for t0τtT and xNtXNt, we have

v(τ)ji(t0,xNt)=v(t0)ji(t,xNit)exp[t0τr(y)dy]=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni![W(τ)Ki(τ,xKit)W(τ)Kiji(τ,xKjit)]=Eτ{Tji(s)exp[τr(y)dy]dsxNi(t)=xtN.t}

The corresponding compensatory is

ji(τ)Δt=Eτ{[vt(τ)ji(t,xNit)|t=τ]ΔtkiNi[vxkit(τ)i(t,xNit)|t=τ]fkiN[τ,xNiτ,ψki(τ)N(τ,xNiτ)]Δt12h,ζ=1niΩNihζ(τ,xτ)[vxthxtζ(τ)ji(t,xt)|t=τ]ΔtkiNi[vxkit(τ)ji(t,xNit)|t=τ]σki[τ,xτ]Δzkiτ}o(Δt)

The imputation is specified as

v(t0)ij(t0,xNi0)=Et0{t0Tji(s)[t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]ds+qji(xji(T))[t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]xNi(t0)=xNi0}=Et0{t0Tji(s)1πrexp[14r(s2t02)]ds+qji(xji(T))1πrexp[14r(T2t02)]xNi(t0)=xNi0}(14)

and for t0τtT and xNtXNt, we have

v(τ)ji(t0,xNt)=v(t0)ji(t,xNit)[t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni![W(τ)Ki(τ,xKit)W(τ)Kiji(τ,xKjit)]=Eτ{tTji(s)[t0sp2πr3exp[p24r]dp]dsxNi(t)=xtNit}(15)

By analyzing the above, it is evident that the imputation mechanism adjusted has the property of strong δ stability. The rest two adjusted Shapley vectors are

v(t0)ij(t0,xNi0)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni![W(t0)K(t0,xKit0)ji=1nigji(sk,x~(s))V(x~(s),Ts;Ni)W(t0)Kiji(t0,xKiji0)ni=1nigji(sk,x~(s))]=Et0{t0Tji(s)1πrexp[14r(s2t02)]ds+qji(xji(T))1πrexp[14r(T2t02)]xNi(t0)=xNi0}(16)

v(t0)ij(t0,xNi0)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!ni![W(t0)K(t0,xKit0)ji=1nigji(sk,x~(s))V(x~(s),Ts;Ni)W(t0)Kiji(t0,xKiji0)ji=1nigji(sk,x~(s))V(x~(s),Ts;Ni)]=Et0{t0Tji(s)1πrexp[14r(s2t02)]ds+qji(xji(T))1πrexp[14r(T2t02)]xNi(t0)=xNi0}(17)

6  The Attractor of Agents’ Behaviour in Deterministic Multi-Local-World Graph

Under the interaction between the agent and the external environment, the economic and management system constantly changes dynamically. If and only if Agent optimal strategy converges to a relatively constant value, the system tends to be stable and can be described as deterministic. Furthermore, if and only if the system state converges to a certain small region, the behavior strategy of each agent in the whole system will tend to a certain deterministic state, which will make the system converge to its attractor as defined by Definition 6 in Supplementary Material.

The convergence of system game results determines the state’s convergence in the process. If the system state equation dx=0, or dxp0, the system state, can be considered as a constant value and also means that x(s) can take specific value in-game objective equation, the problem will be simplified to the classic problem of the game theorem.

The convergence of a random differential game in a deterministic Multi-Local-World graph determines the property that each Agent behavior tends to a constant state in a relatively small time scale, which is proven by Lemma 6, Lemma 7, Lemma 8 and Theorem 8 coupled with corresponding proofs in Supplementary Material. If and only if the Agent behavior in the Multi-Local-World graph remains constant, external environment interference, internal non-leading factors, and fluctuations of those factors can make the innovation. Such innovation may lead to dynamic behaviors for Agent behavior, including creating new reactions with other agents in the same local domain and in different, breaking the relationship with other agents that have reacted with, eliminating by the system, creating new reaction relationships with new agents coming into the system. Those behaviors are the sources of system innovation. And then, the convergence analysis of Agent behavior in a relatively small time scale has very important value. Furthermore, such convergence is deterministic by constraint condition of Agent behavior describing the system characteristics (namely, the convergence of corresponding random differential equation of state dynamics equation). From such a Perspective, the problem will turn to attractor analysis of Eqs. (1) and (6).

The attractor of the equation is disused by introducing a corresponding Lyapunov function ; suppose that

(W(t,x))=Wt(t0)Ki(t,xKi)+12h,ζ=1mΩKihζ(t,xNi)Wxhxζ(t0)Ki(t,xKi)+maxuKi{jiKigji[t,xji,uji]exp[t0tr(y)dy]+jiKiWxji(t0Ki)(t,xKi)fjiKi[t,x,u]}(18)

For Eq. (18), we set ψ(t)=exp[r(tt0)], we have

[ψpα(t)V(t,ϕ)]γ(t)u1(ψα(t)ϕ(0))+τ0ς(θ)u2(ψα(t+θ)ϕ(θ))dθ=γ(t)u1(ψα(t)ϕ(0))+E(u2(ψα(t)ϕ(t)))(19)

Suppose that p=1,ϕ(t)=x(t), according to the property of x(t), we have

[ψα(t)W(t,x)]γ(t)[u1(hα(t,x))u2(hα(t,x))]=γ(t)u(hα(t,x))

We can know there does exist some t,x(t) satisfying u(hα(t,x))=0 such that limt(hα,ker(u))=0. Combining (18), we can see the solution satisfying this condition must be the solution of Eq. (18), so Eq. (18) is the optimal strategy (t,xKit) of the agent Ki, which should be seen in Fig. 2.

images

Figure 2: The property of the attractor of stochastic differential game

These optimal strategies are stable when some degree of disruptions are added sharply, as shown in Fig. 3.

images

Figure 3: The property of attractor of the stochastic differential game when optimal strategy trajectory deviates

The optimal strategies strategy driven by adjusted Shapley value is more stable, as shown in Figs. 1 and 2. The proof is seen Sub-section in 6.2 and Appendix H in the Supplementary Material.

7  Conclusion

The interaction between Agents can be concluded with two kinds of stochastic differential games: cooperative and non-cooperative. The former happens between agents in the same Local-World. However, the latter happens between agents in different Local-World. Agent’s behavior is decided by two factors: the constraint condition driven by a stochastic dynamics equation on resources and the objectivity of payoff maximized within a specific time interval.

In this paper, three different behaviors with the discount function of the homogenous exponential distribution, in-homogenous exponential distribution, and Lévy distribution are analyzed, respectively. By analyzing, it is concluded that the optimal strategy according to the cooperative stochastic differential game in a certain Local-world and the non-cooperative stochastic differential game between different Local-worlds are obtained, respectively. The optimal strategy of a cooperative game is not consistent with the other. It is concluded that a nonlinear operator q=||(gxxt)/(fxxt)|| could couple these two different games together, which produces a Nash-Pareto optimal strategy. Thus, it is known that the different payoff coupled with the optimal strategies of the agent ji according to the behavior of the discount function of the homogenous exponential distribution, in-homogenous exponential distribution, and Lévy distribution, respectively, will be

v(t)ji(t0,xNi0)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!n![exp[r(tt0)]W(t0)Ki(t0,xKi0)qji=1nigji(t,x~(t))V(x~(t),Tt;Ni)exp[r(tt0)]W(t0)Kiji(t0,xKiji0)qji=1nigji(t,x~(t))V(x~(t),Tt;Niji)]

v(t)ji(t0,xNi0)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!n!×[h=1exp[rh(tt0)]Wh(t0)Ki(t0,xKi0)qji=1nigji(t,x~(t))V(x~(t),Tt;Ni)h=1exp[rh(tt0)]Wh(t0)Kiji(t0,xKiji0)qji=1nigji(t,x~(t))V(x~(t),Tt;Niji)]

v(t)ji(t0,xNi0)=KiNi(ki1)!(niki)!n!×[[1πrexp[14r(t2t02)]]W(t0)Ki(t0,xKi0)qji=1nigji(t,x~(t))V(x~(t),Tt;Ni)[1πrexp[14r(t2t02)]]W(t0)Kiji(t0,xKiji0)qji=1nigji(t,x~(t))V(x~(t),Tt;Niji)]

where W is the agent’s optimal payoff coming from the cooperative stochastic differential game in a certain Local-World. The vector (t,x~(t)) denotes the optimal strategy, in which the information vector of transitory resources configuration, agent’s strategy structure, and local topological structure are included, of the agent ji at the time t coupled with the cooperative stochastic differential game in the corresponding Local-World; gji(t,x~(t)) denotes the objective function of the agent ji at time t; V(x~(t),Tt;Ni) denotes the optimal payoff coming from the non-cooperative stochastic differential game between Agents who stand in different Local-Worlds; however, W is the optimal payoff coupled with the optimal solutions.

The optimal strategy is described as a mapping of the optimal strategy of a cooperative game stochastic differential game, and the stability relies on the payoff distribution mechanism. In this paper, we construct an adjusted dynamical stochastic Shapley value

Sh~ji(x0)=KiNi,(jiKi)(niki)!(ki1)!ni![V^(x0,Tt0;Ki)V^(x0,Tt0;Ki{ji})]

The adjusted dynamical stochastic Shapley payoff distribution procedure and the transitory payoff compensatory make the agent’s optimal strategy stable and sustained and make the Agents’ behavior such that the optimal strategy converge into a deterministic attractor.

Funding Statement: This paper is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China, (Grant Nos. 72174064, 71671054, and 61976064); the Natural Science Foundation of Shandong Province, “Dynamic Coordination Mechanism of the Fresh Agricultural Produce Supply Chain Driven by Customer Behavior from the Perspective of Quality Loss” (ZR2020MG004); and Industrial Internet Security Evaluation Service Project (TC210W09P).

Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest to report regarding the present study.

References

    1. T. Hachijo, H. Gotoda, T. Nishizawa and J. Kazawa, “Early detection of cascade flutter in a model aircraft turbine using a methodology combining complex networks and synchronization,” Physical Review Applied, vol. 14, no. 1, pp. 14093, 2020. [Google Scholar]

    2. S. C. Lera, A. Pentland and D. Sornette, “Prediction and prevention of disproportionally dominant agents in complex networks,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, vol. 117, no. 44, pp. 27090–27095, 2020. [Google Scholar]

    3. A. Li, L. Zhou, Q. Su, S. P. Cornelius, Y. Liu et al., “Evolution of cooperation on temporal networks,” Nature Communications, vol. 11, no. 1, pp. 1–9, 2020. [Google Scholar]

    4. M. A. Javarone, “Poker as a skill game: Rational versus irrational behaviors,” Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment, vol. 2015, no. 3, pp. P3018, 2015. [Google Scholar]

    5. A. Mcavoy, B. Allen and M. A. Nowak, “Social goods dilemmas in heterogeneous societies,” Nature Human Behaviour, vol. 4, no. 8, pp. 819–831, 2020. [Google Scholar]

    6. S. Gächter, B. Herrmann and C. Thöni, “Culture and cooperation,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, vol. 365, no. 1553, pp. 2651–2661, 2010. [Google Scholar]

    7. A. J. Calvert, K. Ramachandran, H. Kao and M. A. Fisher, “Local thickening of the cascadia forearc crust and the origin of seismic reflectors in the uppermost mantle,” Tectonophysics, vol. 420, no. 1–2, pp. 175–188, 2006. [Google Scholar]

    8. T. L. Friesz and K. Han, “The mathematical foundations of dynamic user equilibrium,” Transportation Research Part B-Methodological, vol. 126, pp. 309–328, 2019. [Google Scholar]

    9. P. L. Querini, O. Chiotti and E. Fernádez, “Cooperative energy management system for networked microgrids,” Sustainable Energy Grids and Networks, vol. 23, pp. 100371, 2020. [Google Scholar]

  10. F. Chighoub and B. Mezerdi, “The relationship between the stochastic maximum principle and the dynamic programming in singular control of jump diffusions,” International Journal of Stochastic Analysis, vol. 2014, pp. 1–17, 2014. [Google Scholar]

  11. L. Guo and J. J. Ye, “Necessary optimality conditions for optimal control problems with equilibrium constraints,” Siam Journal on Control and Optimization, vol. 54, no. 5, pp. 2710–2733, 2016. [Google Scholar]

  12. M. I. Gomoyunov, “On viscosity solutions of path-dependent Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman–Isaacs equations for fractional-order systems,” arXiv preprint arXiv:2109.02451, 2021. [Google Scholar]

  13. G. Giallombardo, F. Guerriero and G. Miglionico, “Profit maximization via capacity control for distribution logistics problems,” arXiv preprint arXiv:2008.03216, 2020. [Google Scholar]

  14. D. Kosz, “Dichotomy property for maximal operators in a nondoubling setting,” Bulletin of the Australian Mathematical Society, vol. 99, no. 3, pp. 454–466, 2019. [Google Scholar]

  15. Y. Filmus, J. Oren and K. Soundararajan, “Shapley values in weighted voting games with random weights,” arXiv preprint arXiv:1601.06223, 2016. [Google Scholar]

  16. X. J. Zheng, X. S. Xu and C. C. Luo, “Agent behaviors and coordinative mechanism,” Kybernetes, vol. 41, no. 10, pp. 1586–1603, 2012. [Google Scholar]

  17. D. W. Yeung and L. A. Petrosjan, Cooperative Stochastic Differential Games, New York, USA: Springer Science & Business Media, pp. 1586–1603, 2006. [Google Scholar]


Cite This Article

APA Style
Yu, X., Wang, C., Zheng, X., Zeng, C., Gupta, B.B. (2023). Optimal strategies trajectory with multi-local-worlds graph. Computers, Materials & Continua, 75(1), 2079-2099. https://doi.org/10.32604/cmc.2023.034118
Vancouver Style
Yu X, Wang C, Zheng X, Zeng C, Gupta BB. Optimal strategies trajectory with multi-local-worlds graph. Comput Mater Contin. 2023;75(1):2079-2099 https://doi.org/10.32604/cmc.2023.034118
IEEE Style
X. Yu, C. Wang, X. Zheng, C. Zeng, and B. B. Gupta, “Optimal Strategies Trajectory with Multi-Local-Worlds Graph,” Comput. Mater. Contin., vol. 75, no. 1, pp. 2079-2099, 2023. https://doi.org/10.32604/cmc.2023.034118


cc Copyright © 2023 The Author(s). Published by Tech Science Press.
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License , which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
  • 721

    View

  • 429

    Download

  • 0

    Like

Share Link